Competitive pricing on online markets: a literature review

  • Research Article
  • Open access
  • Published: 14 June 2022
  • Volume 21 , pages 596–622, ( 2022 )

Cite this article

You have full access to this open access article

research paper on competitive market

  • Torsten J. Gerpott 1 &
  • Jan Berends 1  

23k Accesses

8 Citations

Explore all metrics

Past reviews of studies concerning competitive pricing strategies lack a unifying approach to interdisciplinarily structure research across economics, marketing management, and operations. This academic void is especially unfortunate for online markets as they show much higher competitive dynamics compared to their offline counterparts. We review 132 articles on competitive posted goods pricing on either e-tail markets or markets in general. Our main contributions are (1) to develop an interdisciplinary framework structuring scholarly work on competitive pricing models and (2) to analyze in how far research on offline markets applies to online retail markets.

Similar content being viewed by others

research paper on competitive market

Pricing Strategies in the Electronic Marketplace

Can online retailers escape the law of one price.

research paper on competitive market

Platform Competition: Market Structure and Pricing

Avoid common mistakes on your manuscript.

Introduction

Setting prices relative to competitors, i.e., competitive pricing, Footnote 1 is a classical marketing problem which has been studied extensively before the emergence of e-commerce (Talluri and van Ryzin 2004 ; Vives 2001 ). Although literature on online pricing has been reviewed in the past (Ratchford 2009 ), interrelations between pricing and competition were rarely considered systematically (Li et al. 2017 ). As less than 2% of high-impact journal articles address pricing issues (Toni et al. 2017 ), pricing strategies do not receive proper research attention according to their practical relevance. This research gap holds even more for competitive pricing. In the past, the monopolistic assumption that demand for homogeneous goods mostly depends on prices set by a single firm may have been a viable simplification since price comparisons were difficult. Today, consumer search costs Footnote 2 shrink as the prices of most goods can be compared on relatively transparent online markets. Therefore, demand is increasingly influenced by prices of competitors which therefore should not be ignored (Lin and Sibdari 2009 ).

In the early 1990s, few people anticipated that business-to-consumer (B2C) online goods retail markets Footnote 3 would develop from a dubious alternative to conventional “brick-and-mortar” retail stores to an omnipresent distribution channel for all kinds of products in less than two decades (Balasubramanian 1998 ; Boardman and McCormick 2018 ). In 2000, e-commerce accounted for a mere 1% of overall retail sales. In 2025, e-retail sales are projected to account for nearly 25% of global retail sales (Lebow 2019 ). Traditional offline channels are nowadays typically complemented by online technologies (Gao and Su 2018 ). With digitization of various societal sectors in general and the COVID-19 pandemic in particular, the shift toward online channels is unlikely to stop in the future. Besides direct online shops, two-thirds of e-commerce sales are sold through online marketplaces/platforms like Alibaba, Amazon or eBay (Young 2022 ). The marketplace operator acts as an intermediary (two-sided platform) who matches demand (online consumers) with supply (retailers). Whereas the retailer retains control over product assortment and prices, he has to pay a commission to the marketplace operator (Hagiu 2007 ). However, these intermediaries often act as sellers themselves, thereby posing direct competition to retailers who have to decide between direct or marketplace channels (Ryan et al. 2012 ).

Online consumer markets fundamentally differ from offline settings (Chintagunta et al. 2012 ; Lee and Tan 2003 ; Scarpi et al. 2014 ; Smith and Brynjolfsson 2001 ). Factors which make competition even more prevalent for online than for offline markets are summarized in Table 1 .

To date, a number of scholarly articles reviews various aspects of pricing under competition or online pricing (Boer 2015a ; Chen and Chen 2015 ; Cheng 2017 ; Kopalle et al. 2009 ; Ratchford 2009 ; Vives 2001 ). Vives ( 2001 ) provides an overview of the history of pricing theory and its evolution from the early work of Bertrand ( 1883 ) who studied a duopoly with unconstrained capacity and identical products to Dudey ( 1992 ) who set the foundation for today’s dynamic pricing Footnote 4 research with constrained capacities and a finite sales horizon. Ratchford ( 2009 ) reviews the influence of online markets on pricing strategies. Although he depicts factors shaping the competitive environment of online markets and compares online versus offline channels, he does not include competitive strategies specifically. This also holds for review papers on dynamic pricing which treat competition rather novercally (Boer 2015a ; Gönsch et al. 2009 ). With emphasis on mobility barriers, multimarket contact and mutual forbearance, Cheng ( 2017 ) studies competition mechanisms across strategic groups. Kopalle et al. ( 2009 ) discuss competitive effects in retail focusing on different aspects such as manufacturer interaction and cross-channel competition. To the best of our knowledge, Chen and Chen ( 2015 ) are the only scholars who review existing competitive pricing research by classifying model characteristics along product uniqueness (identical vs. differentiated), type of customer (myopic vs. strategic), pricing policy (contingent vs. preannounced) and number of competitors (duopoly vs. oligopoly). However, competition is only one of three pricing problems they analyze forcing them to reduce scope and depth and to exclude online peculiarities. In addition, significant competitive pricing contributions were published since 2015 (chapter 2.2). Overall, given the limitations of previous reviews of the pricing literature makes revisiting the current state of research a worthwhile undertaking.

Most often, competitive pricing literature uses simplifying assumptions limiting the applicability of presented models. The simplifications are required to circumvent challenges like the curse of dimensionality (Harsha et al. 2019 ; Kastius and Schlosser 2022 ; Li et al. 2017 ; Schlosser and Boissier 2018 ), endogeneity problems (Cebollada et al. 2019 ; Chu et al. 2008 ; Fisher et al. 2018 ; Villas-Boas and Winer 1999 ), uncertain information (Adida and Perakis 2010 ; e.g., Bertsimas and Perakis 2006 ; Chung et al. 2012 ; Ferreira et al. 2016 ; Keskin and Zeevi 2017 ; Shugan 2002 ) and simultaneity bias (Li et al. 2017 ). As a consequence, early work on pricing strategies with competition was restricted to theoretical discussions (Caplin and Nalebuff 1991 ; Mizuno 2003 ; Perloff and Salop 1985 ). This holds especially true in combination with other practical circumstances such as capacity constraints, time-varying demand or a finite selling horizon (Gallego and Hu 2014 ).

Armstrong and Green ( 2007 ) find empirical evidence that competitive pricing, especially for the sake of gaining market share, harms profitability. Similarly, some researchers cursorily ascribe competitor-based pricing as a sign of a poor management because it signals a lack of capabilities to set prices independently (Larson 2019 ). Revenue management researchers therefore often assume that monopoly pricing models implicitly capture the dynamic effects of competition. The so-called market response hypothesis is the key rationale to neglect the effects of competition altogether (Phillips 2021 ; Talluri and van Ryzin 2004 ). According to this reasoning, competition does not have to be considered as all relevant effects are already included in historical sales data. However, this intuitive argument can be easily rebutted as Simon ( 1979 ) already showed that price elasticities change over time. Furthermore, Cooper et al. ( 2015 ) study the validity of the market response hypothesis and conclude that this monopolistic view is rarely adequate. Monopolistic pricing models can only be applied to stable markets with little time-varying demand and little expected competitive reactions.

Detrimental outcomes of ignoring competition in pricing strategies are shown by Anufriev et al. ( 2013 ), Bischi et al. ( 2004 ), Isler and Imhof ( 2008 ), Schinkel et al. ( 2002 ), and Tuinstra (2004). The negative effects are even more harmful in fierce competitive settings such as situations with a high number of competitors or price sensitive customers (van de Geer et al. 2019 ). Empirical evidence on the influence of competition on pricing decisions is provided by Richards and Hamilton ( 2006 ) who find that retailers compete on price and variety for market share. Li et al. ( 2017 ) observe that competition-based variables explained 30.2% of hotel price variations in New York—compared to 22.3% attributed to demand-side variables. Similarly, Hinterhuber ( 2008 ) assesses competitor-based pricing as a dominant strategy from a practical perspective. Li et al. ( 2008 ) argue that because of its relevance, competition should be considered in operational revenue management and not be treated stepmotherly as an abstract strategic constraint.

Although striving to simplify pricing models is desirable, researchers should thus not simply ignore effects of competition on price setting in a non-monopolistic (online) world. Blindly pegging pricing strategies to competitors or undercutting competitors to gain market share may favor detrimental price wars and not profit-maximizing market structures. Nevertheless, no significant market player can operate isolated on online markets—decisions made always affect competing firms and consumer demand (Chiang et al. 2007 ). In such dynamic markets (chapter 3.3), competition must be considered with time-varying attributes (Schlosser et al. 2016 ).

Against this background, we suggest a conceptual framework to structure research covering competitive online pricing. It can serve scholars as a map to direct future research on the one hand and provide practicing managers with a guide to locate relevant pricing contributions on the other hand. Although the framework can be applied to a variety of markets with competitive dynamics, we concentrate our review on research covering B2C online goods retail markets. Thus, related research with a focus on auction pricing, multichannel peculiarities, behavioral pricing and multi-dimensional pricing approaches such as Everything-as-a-Service (XaaS) or bundle pricing is only assessed when findings are crucial to the competition-related discussion. In the remainder, we proceed as follows. The next chapter provides a descriptive overview of the competitive pricing literature for the subsequent discussion. Chapter 3 puts the identified literature into the perspective of online retail markets considering product and environmental characteristics. Section 4 concludes with practical implications and directions for future research.

Overview of competitive pricing research

Initially, properties of the reviewed literature are briefly summarized. Besides (a) the journal representation, (b) the historical development of online market considerations and (c) research domains, we classify research according to (d) the geographical and industry context as well as (e) research design and empirical foundation.

We identified relevant references through a semi-structured multi-pronged search strategy. Following Tranfield et al. ( 2003 ), we firstly screened the literature reviews mentioned in chapter 1 to obtain an overview of existing research streams. Second, we created a set of potentially relevant contributions by searching multiple keywords in the journal databases EBSCO, Scopus and Web of Science (c.f. Baloglu and Assante 1999 ). Footnote 5 Third, high-impact journals (see Appendix 1) in the academic fields economics, marketing management, and operations were screened. With focus on highly cited (> 10 citations in Scopus), recent (published later than 2000) research, we identified an initial sample of 996 unique papers. Fourth, we studied the abstract and skimmed the text of all papers for relevance to competitive online pricing, reducing our initial set to 174 papers. Fifth, we screened the references of the papers and identified literature cited which we not already included in our set. Sixth, especially for research areas with limited coverage in peer-reviewed journals, we uncovered gray literature through searches with Google Scholar. As a result, this study concentrates on papers published between 2000 and 2022 and only sparsely utilizes literature from the pre-internet era. The final sample of the papers with relevance to competitive B2C online pricing encompasses 132 entries. A complete list of the papers reviewed in great depth is provided in Appendix 2. 94% are peer-reviewed articles. Book chapters, conference papers and preprint/working papers each account for 2%.

Journal representation

Competitive pricing literature is widely dispersed over a broad range of journals as roughly half of the articles considered are from journals with less than three articles in our review. Notably, journals with a higher density of competitive pricing contributions are from the fields of operations, economics or are interdisciplinary. Table 2 reports the distribution of articles among the journals with the highest representation. In addition, it provides the considered articles subject to a content analysis in chapter 3.

Online pricing contributions over time

Between 1976 and the end of the second millennium, the number of papers on competitive pricing in an internet context is naturally limited (Fig.  1 ). Parallel to the dissemination of online use among residential households, interest of researchers in online pricing in a competitive environment started to take off. 71.8% of the papers published from 2015 to 2022 consider online settings specifically. The corresponding statistic from 2000 to 2005 amounts to 43.8%.

figure 1

Competitive pricing literature and its consideration of online peculiarities accumulated by year

Development of research domains

Competitive pricing literature typically can be assigned to one of the following research domains:

The economics domain takes a market perspective across individual firms. It elaborates on the existence and uniqueness of competitive equilibria also including all subjects regarding econometrics.

The marketing management domain analyzes competitive pricing problems from the perspective of a single firm with a focus on customer reactions to pricing decisions. It includes all subjects linked to marketing, strategy, business, international, technology, innovation, and general management.

The operations domain considers quantitative pricing solutions for, among others, quantity planning, choice of distribution channels, and detection of algorithm driven price collusion. It includes all subjects regarding computer science, industrial and manufacturing engineering, and mathematics.

Separating the last 47 years of competitive pricing research into three intervals, all reviewed papers are assigned to their most affiliated research domain. Although the domains are similarly represented in our review (see Fig.  2 ), we see differences in their temporal change. Whereas rather theoretical economic subjects are covered relatively constant over time, more practice-oriented marketing management and operations subjects gained momentum since 2000. This suggests a shift from model conceptualization toward applicable research, frequently based on empirical data.

figure 2

Distribution of competitive pricing literature over research domain and time interval

Geographical and industry context

As the origin of revenue management lies in transportation and hospitality optimization problems, one could expect that competitive pricing research also originates in these dynamic sectors. However, our analysis reveals a different picture: Almost half of the papers in our review do not concentrate on a specific industry. Besides, most industry-specific competitive pricing articles focus on retail, with 38% concentrating on the retail industry versus 8% and 4% on transportation and hospitality, respectively (see Fig.  3 ). This supports our proposition in chapter 1 that effects of competition on industry-specific pricing are particularly relevant for online markets.

figure 3

Competitive pricing research by focal industry and location of lead authors’ institution

Competitive pricing literature is predominantly driven by researchers employed by U.S. institutions (60%). The remaining 40% consist of Europe (19%), Asia (17%) and Canada (4%).

Research approach

A lack of empirical testing is an issue that hampers competitive pricing research. Liozu ( 2015 ) reported that only 15% of general pricing literature include empirical data. For competitive pricing, the situation appears even more aggravated. In addition to parameters such as price elasticities and stock levels of the company under study, comprehensive, real-time information of other market participants is crucial to add practical value.

For instance, to solve a simple Bertrand equilibrium, Footnote 6 full information of all competitors is needed, which is rarely available in real-life settings. Therefore, many problems covered in the literature are of a theoretical nature. In accordance with Liozu ( 2015 ), we find that only 18% of reviewed articles use empirical evidence to validate hypotheses. An additional 23% strive to ameliorate this shortage through simulation data and numerical examples. The remaining 59% fail to bring any empirical evidence or numerical examples.

As can be taken from Fig.  4 , missing empirical support is particularly prevalent for equilibrium models which use empirical data in only 7% of all papers.

figure 4

Competitive pricing research by research design and empirical validation

Competitive pricing on online markets

In this chapter, we assess the applicability of competitive pricing work to online markets. Typical characteristics of competitive B2C pricing models were derived from literature described in chapter 2. Competitive pricing literature can be classified along four characteristics depicted in Table 3 that form the market environment in which firms compete for consumer demand.

In the remainder of chapter 3, we discuss the four key questions in more depth and elaborate on their applicability to online retail markets.

Product similarity

In general, products in competitive pricing models are either identical (homogeneous) or differentiated by at least one quality parameter (heterogeneous). In case of homogeneous products, pricing is the only purchase decision variable—a perfectly competitive setting (Chen and Chen 2015 ). However, many firms strive to differentiate their products as this shifts the focus from the price as competitive lever to other product-related features (Afeche et al. 2011 ; Boyd and Bilegan 2003 ; Thomadsen 2007 ). According to Lancaster ( 1979 ), there are two types of product differentiation: vertical and horizontal differentiation. Vertical differentiation Footnote 7 encompasses all product distinctions which are objectively measurable and quantifiable regarding their quality level. Horizontal differentiation Footnote 8 can manifest in many variants and includes all product-related aspects which cannot be quantified according to their quality levels. Footnote 9 A key difference in the modeling of substitutable yet differentiated versus identical goods is that customers have heterogenous preferences among products. Footnote 10 A recent stream of literature approaches unknown differentiation criteria by assessing online consumer-generated content (DeSarbo and Grewal 2007 ; Lee and Bradlow 2011 ; Netzer et al. 2012 ; Ringel and Skiera 2016 ; Won et al. 2022 ).

Besides the chosen price level, Cachon and Harker ( 2002 ) argue that firms compete with the operational performance level offered and perceived, i.e., service level in online retail, to differentiate an otherwise homogenous offering. In situations, where resellers with comparable service and shipping policies offer similar products, price is a major decision variable for potential buyers (Yang et al. 2020 ). Often, e-tailers do not possess the right to exclusively distribute a certain product. For example, Samsung’s Galaxy S21 5G was offered by 69 resellers on the German price comparison website Idealo.de. Footnote 11 As some products in e-tail can be differentiated and others cannot, both identical and differentiated product research have their raison d’être for competitive online pricing.

Most competitive pricing models only address the effects of single-product settings. This simplification is reasonable if there is no interdependence between products of an e-tailer (Gönsch et al. 2009 ). Taking up on the smartphone example, the prices of close substitutes, such as Huawei’s P30 Pro, nonetheless have an impact on the demand of Samsung’s Galaxy S21 5G. To further extent product differentiation, price models have to incorporate multi-product pricing problems in non-cooperative settings (Chen and Chen 2015 ). Such models have to account not only for demand impact of directly competing products but also for synergies, cannibalization/substitution effects of (own) differentiated goods. Although there is a recent research stream regarding product assortment (Besbes and Sauré 2016 ; Federgruen and Hu 2015 ; Heese and Martínez-de-Albéniz 2018 ; Nip et al. 2020 ; Sun and Gilbert 2019 ), multi-product work is still underdeveloped. Thus, competitive multi-product pricing constitutes an area which should be addressed in future research.

Product durability

The durability of products is an important feature to differentiate between competitive pricing model types. Durable (non-perishable) products do not have an expiration date, for example consumer durables such as household appliances. Perishable products can only be sold for a limited time interval and have a finite sales horizon. After expiration date, unused capacity is lost or significantly devalued to a salvage value. Footnote 12 Combined with limited capacities, the firm objective is thus most often to maximize turnover under capacity constraints and finite sales horizon (Gallego and van Ryzin 1997 ; McGill and van Ryzin 1999 ; Weatherford and Bodily 1992 ).

Perishability can be of relevance for products with seasonality effects or short product life cycles (i.e., finite selling horizon) such as apparel, food groceries or winter sports equipment. This is especially relevant because online retailers of perishable products are severely restricted in their shipment, return handle policies and supply chain length (Cattani et al. 2007 ). Sellers cannot replenish their inventory after the planning phase and cannot retain goods for future sales periods (Perakis and Sood 2006 ). Some products like apparel—albeit reducing in value after a selling season—still have a certain salvage value and can be sold at reduced prices (Anand and Girotra 2007 ).

It depends on the type of product to decide whether perishability should be included in competitive pricing models. There is a fundamental distinction in the underlying optimization objective for models with or without perishability. Whereas models with perishable products tend to focus on revenue maximization over a definite short-term time horizon, models with durable products tend to focus on profit maximization over an indefinite or at least long-term time horizon by balancing current revenues of existing and future revenues of new customers. To account for this trade-off, models with durable products need to discount future cash flows incorporating time value of money, stock-keeping, opportunity and other costs related to prolonged sales (Farias et al. 2012 ). To conclude, perishability cannot be treated as an extension to durable models but rather as a separate class of pricing models. Depending on the product and/or setting in focus, both are relevant for online retailing. Further research could investigate the performance of models with and without consideration of perishability in various (online) settings to determine when it is appropriate to use which class of pricing models. Also, an interesting field of future studies arises around the question which instruments (e.g., service differentiations or price diffusion) are used by online retailers to differentiate otherwise homogeneous offerings.

Time dependence

A key differentiator of competitive pricing models is the consideration of either a static (time-independent) setup with definite equilibrium or a dynamic (time-dependent) constellation with changing environmental factors and equilibria. Albeit static pricing models have no time component, many consist of multiple stages to investigate the interplay of different factors. Footnote 13 In contrast, dynamic models allow for varying competitive (re-)actions over time. Footnote 14 Within the latter category, there are models with a finite (Afeche et al. 2011 ; Levin et al. 2008 ; Liu and Zhang 2013 ; Yang and Xia 2013 ) and an infinite (Anderson and Kumar 2007 ; Li et al. 2017 ; Schlosser and Richly 2019 ; Villas-Boas and Winer 1999 ; Weintraub et al. 2008 ) time horizon.

Historically, competitive pricing models assumed fixed prices over the considered time horizon. Limited computational power made it impossible to appropriately estimate models dynamically due to dimensionality issues (Schlosser and Boissier 2018 ). A lack of reliable demand information, high menu and investment costs to implement dynamic approaches were additional reasons why pricing models remained inherently static without incorporating changing competitive responses (Ferreira et al. 2016 ). The focus in retail has conventionally rather been on long-term profit optimization and to a lesser degree on dynamically changing price optimizations (Elmaghraby and Keskinocak 2003 ).

The literature disagrees on whether firms should opt for static or dynamic pricing strategies. A static environment allows to simplify and concentrate on a specific topic such as equilibrium discussions. For instance, Lal and Rao ( 1997 ) study success factors of everyday low pricing and derive conditions for a perfect Nash equilibrium between an everyday low price retailer and a retailer with promotional pricing. With Zara as an example for a company with a successful static pricing strategy, Liu and Zhang ( 2013 ) argue that with the presence of strategic customers who prolong sales in anticipation of price decreases, firms might even be better off to deploy static over dynamic price setting processes. Studying the time-variant pricing plans in electricity markets, Schlereth et al. ( 2018 ) suggest that consumers might prefer static over dynamic pricing because of factors like choice confusion, lack of trust in price fairness, perceived economical risk or perceived additional effort. Further support for a static pricing strategy is found in Cachon and Feldman ( 2010 ) and Hall et al. ( 2009 ).

Nevertheless, to generalize that static should strictly be preferred over dynamic pricing models could be short-sighted. Firms cannot generally infer future behavior of competitors from past observations to assess how competitive (re-) actions may influence the optimal pricing policy (Boer 2015b ). Corresponding to the surge of revenue management systems in the airline industry during the 70s and 80s, increased price and demand transparency, low menu costs and an abundance of decision support software created fierce competition among online retailers (Fisher et al. 2018 ). Taking up on the above mentioned example by Liu and Zhang ( 2013 ), Caro and Gallien ( 2012 ) show that even Zara does not solely rely on static pricing. They supported Zara’s pricing team in designing and implementing a dynamic clearance pricing optimization system—to generate a competitive advantage in addition to the fast-fashion retail model Zara mainly pursues (Caro 2012 ). Zhang et al. ( 2017 ) discuss various duopoly pricing models with static and dynamic pricing under advertising. They find that market surplus is highest when one firm prices dynamically, profiting from the static behavior of the other. Chung et al. ( 2012 ) provide numerical evidence that a dynamic pricing model with an appropriately specified demand estimation always outperforms static pricing strategies—also in settings with incomplete information. Xu and Hopp ( 2006 ) show that dynamic pricing outperforms preannounced pricing, especially with effective inventory management and elastic demand. Further support for advantages of dynamic pricing can be found by Popescu ( 2015 ), Wang and Sun ( 2019 ), and Zhang et al. ( 2018b ). Empirical evidence of the negative consequences of sticking to a static strategy in a changing environment is found in the cases of Nokia, Kodak, and Xerox.

While some scholars distinguish between discrete and continuous dynamic pricing systems (Vinod 2020 ), we suggest to classify dynamic pricing models according to their level of sophistication into two evolutionary stages: the (in e-commerce widely applied) manual rule-based pricing approach and the data-driven algorithmic optimization approach (Popescu 2015 ; Le Chen et al. 2016 ). Footnote 15 For the rule-based approach, “if-then-else rules” are defined and updated manually. Footnote 16 However, the mere number of stock-keeping units (SKUs) in today’s retailer offerings aggravate the initial setup and handling of rule-based pricing and make real-time adjustments unmanageable (Schlosser and Boissier 2018 ). In addition, rule-based approaches are rather subjective than sufficiently data-driven. Faced with a large range of SKUs, competitor responses and heterogeneous demand elasticities, canceling out the human decision-making process on an operational level is the next evolutionary step for competitive pricing systems (Calvano et al. 2020 ). Data-driven algorithmic pricing strategies use observable market Footnote 17 data to predict sales probabilities based on consumer demand and competitive responses (Schlosser and Richly 2019 ).

As online marketplaces benefit from an increased number of retailers on their platforms, they typically support sellers to establish automated dynamic pricing systems (Kachani et al. 2010 ). Footnote 18 However, Schlosser and Richly ( 2019 ) claim that current dynamic pricing systems are not able to deal with the complexity of competitor-based pricing and therefore most often ignore competition altogether or solely rely on manually adjusted rule-based mechanics. Challenges include the indefinite spectrum of changing competitor strategies, asymmetric access to competitor knowledge, a large solution space under limited information and the black-box character of dynamic systems, which exacerbates an intervention in case of a pricing system malfunction. Besides, researchers did not yet identify an algorithm which consistently outperforms other methodologies in competitive situations. Instead, it depends on the specific setting and other competitors’ pricing behavior to assess which pricing algorithm is optimal (van de Geer et al. 2019 ) exacerbating the application of such systems.

Reflecting the literature findings for both static and dynamic pricing strategies, we conclude that pricing managers should develop dynamic pricing models in most e-commerce situations. As long as demand and competitor price responses vary over time on online markets, dynamic models are naturally superior to time-independent approaches. Static models on the other hand are only appropriate in market constellations with little time-varying demand and competitor behavior. As static research can be expected to remain a vivid field of literature, further research with regard to the transferability of static models to dynamic settings is desirable. In addition, more research is needed that helps to better understand the implications of widely applied rule-based dynamic pricing methods and their transition toward algorithmic approaches (Boer 2015a ; van de Geer et al. 2019 ; Kastius and Schlosser 2022 ; Könönen 2006 ).

Market structure

The market structure describes the number of competing firms such as duopoly or oligopoly in a demand setting with an indefinite number of consumers. 60% of the reviewed papers studied duopolies, 49% oligopolies, 7% monopolistic competition, and 3% perfect competition. Footnote 19

Especially for research in the economics stream, many papers assume a perfectly competitive market. Pricing research with perfectly competitive markets (e.g., van Mieghem and Dada 1999 or Yang and Xia 2013 ) is likely to be of very limited value to online retailers. Building on the notion of Diamond ( 1971 ), Salop ( 1976 ) argues that if customers have positive information gathering costs, no perfect competition can occur as firms have room to slightly increase prices without losing demand. Christen ( 2005 ) found evidence that even with strong competition and low information costs, cost uncertainty could decrease the detrimental effect of competition for sellers and could increase prices above Bertrand levels. Similarly, Bryant ( 1980 ) showed that perfect competition is not possible in a market with uncertain demand, even if the number of firms is large and customers have no search costs. Rather, price dispersion reflects uncertain demand (Borenstein and Rose Nancy L. 1994 ; Cavallo 2018 ; Clemons et al. 2002 ; Obermeyer et al. 2013 ; Wang et al. 2021 ). Israeli et al. ( 2022 ) empirically show that the market power of individual firms does not only depend on the number and intensity of competitors but also on the firm’s ability to adjust prices in response to varying inventory levels of product substitutes, especially with low consumer search costs. This is of relevance for e-commerce as e-tailers could exploit this dependence by incorporating competitors’ stock levels into pricing decisions (Fisher et al. 2018 ).

Some papers discuss (quasi) monopolistic competition (e.g., Xu and Hopp 2006 ) in which small firms charge the (higher) monopoly price rather than the (lower) competitive price. From an empirical study in the U.S. airline industry, Chen (2018) concludes that, as firms can price discriminate late-arriving consumers, competition is softened, profits are increased, and the only single-price equilibrium could be at the monopoly price. This supports Lal and Sarvary ( 1999 ) who show that online retailers enjoy a certain amount of monopoly power in cases where buyers cannot switch suppliers for repeated purchases (e.g., technical incompatibility reasons). In such cases, switching costs could increase online prices (Chen and Riordan 2008 ). However, this contradicts Deck and Gu ( 2012 ) who empirically show that, although the distribution of buyer values of competing products might theoretically lead to higher prices through competition, intensity of competition rarely allows for an occurrence of this phenomenon in e-tail settings.

Although duopoly settings can serve to assess the relevant strength of pricing strategies, which is not directly possible for oligopoly markets due to the curse of dimensionality (Kastius and Schlosser 2022 ), they cannot be transferred to more competitive environments (van de Geer et al. 2019 ). In online retail, a duopoly market structure is a rare exemption. Like for perfectly competitive markets, findings of duopoly research must be carefully assessed in terms of their applicability to online retail oligopolies.

Bresnahan and Reiss ( 1991 ) found empirical evidence that markets with an increasing number of dealers have lower prices than in less competitive market structures such as monopolies or duopolies. Although applicable to many online retail markets, where retailers face dozens, if not hundreds of thousands of competitors (Schlosser and Boissier 2018 ), few research attention is currently given toward a structure with a large number of competitors in an imperfect market (cf. Li et al. 2017 ). A way to assess the current competitive structure of markets is the utilization of online consumer-generated content such as forum entries (Netzer et al. 2012 ; Won et al. 2022 ) or clickstream data (Ringel and Skiera 2016 ) and actual sales data (Kim et al. 2011 ).

In many countries with well-developed B2C online markets, one or few major retailers dominate on an oligopolistic market. For example, the top three online retailers in the United States accounted for over 50% of the revenue generated on the national e-commerce market in 2021. Footnote 20 Due to lower locational limitations in conjunction with substantial economies of scale and scope, online markets tend to become more concentrated than their offline counterparts (Borsenberger 2015 ). Although one could expect that increased market transparency leads to a higher intensity of competition (Cao and Gruca 2003 ), limiting the market power of established firms and leaving growth potential for smaller firms (Zhao et al. 2017 ), it appears reasonable to predict that most online markets will ultimately resemble an oligopoly setting with a with a relatively small number of players—enabling increased tacit pricing algorithm collusion in the future (Calvano et al. 2020 ). With few exceptions (e.g., Noel 2007 ), there is little research (Brown and Goolsbee 2002 ; Wang et al. 2021 ; Cavallo 2018 ) exploring what type of competitor-based pricing strategies are used and what competitive dynamics are found on e-tail markets. Thus, more research is needed to investigate the current state of market structure and intensity of competition in today’s e-commerce markets as drivers of the selection and the outcomes of pricing approaches.

Implications and directions

We contribute to the literature by providing an interdisciplinary review of competitive online retail research. Competitive pricing problems can most often be assigned to one of the academic fields of economics, marketing management or operations. In a first step, this review offered a descriptive portrayal of the relevant literature. Motivated by practical issues and common features in competitive pricing research, we then structured competitive pricing contributions along four properties of pricing models. First, do firms compete with identical or quality differentiated products? Second, are products to be considered as perishable or durable goods? Third, is the market setting to be regarded time-independent or not? Fourth, which market structure prevails on e-tail markets? The framework is derived from an analysis of pricing research not exclusively restricted to online retail settings. Therefore, it could be extended to other online or offline markets, with little loss of generalizability.

We focused on e-tail markets because the relevance of competition for pricing strategies is disproportionally higher in such environments. On e-tail online markets, products are rarely offered exclusively so that the likelihood of substitutive competition is high. Nevertheless, products can be differentiated through other factors than prices such as generous shipping, customer retention (e.g., loyalty reward programs) or return and issue handling policies. With a look on product similarities, accounting for product interdependencies and multi-product situations are important improvements of prevailing pricing models. Second, pricing models with both a focus on perishable and/or durable products are relevant on e-tail markets. However, further research is needed exploring which of the respective perishability considerations are appropriate for different settings. Third, we conclude that, albeit time-independent static models may occasionally serve to simplify pricing issues, dynamic models outperform their static counterparts in constantly changing market environments such as in e-commerce. Fourth, we show that in most practical settings, online markets resemble either an oligopolistic market structure or a structure with many firms under imperfect competition. Thus, future research should consider these two “real” competitive settings instead of further looking at simplifying market structures such as monopolistic or duopolistic competition. This should ease a transfer of theoretical insights into practical applications. To sum, firms should be able to improve their competitive position by developing a profit optimizing dynamic pricing strategy for identical products in an oligopolistic setting with a varying number and relevance of competitors.

Due to space limitations, we had to focus on competitive pricing model characteristics related to four overall product and market attributes. Thus, more work is needed on other characteristics of competitive pricing models, particularly firm- and consumer-related characteristics. Firm-related characteristics encompass various additional properties of interacting firms (e.g., similarity or capacity constraints). Similarly, consumer-related characteristics entail further properties of interacting buyers (e.g., certainty, discreteness, sophistication, and homogeneity of demand).

In the selection process of literature, this study only considered papers in peer-reviewed journals and conference proceedings in English. Subsequent research could complement our findings by including industry-funded, unpublished and non-peer-reviewed articles, also in other languages. In addition, we do not claim that our research captures all competitive pricing publications of the considered field. As our study spans almost 50 years of a frequently discussed topic in the domains of economics, marketing management, and operations, we had to constrain the scope to the most influential work. Although we mutually evaluated our selection decisions and consulted outside peers for validation and further input, we cannot eliminate the element of subjectivity. Consequently, other authors could have selected slightly different papers. However, this shortcoming is unlikely to significantly affect our results as our literature selection was derived from a broad array of competitive pricing research and would therefore be only marginally influenced by a few omitted articles.

Competitive pricing includes all activities and processes to price products with the consideration of competitors. This does not only include rigidly pegging prices to competitor prices but rather a comprehensive consideration of current and expected price (re-)actions of competing firms to sustainably ensure profit maximization. In this article, the terms competitive pricing, competitor-oriented pricing and competitor-based pricing are used synonymously.

Search costs are defined as the costs of time and resources to acquire information with respect to price, assortment, and quality characteristics of the goods provided by different sellers. The internet dramatically reduces search costs through price comparison websites such as Google Shopping, Shopzilla (USA) or Idealo (Germany).

Business-to-consumer (B2C) online retail sales encompass all forms of electronic commerce markets in which residential end customers can directly buy goods from a seller over the internet through a web browser or a mobile app. In this paper, the terms business-to-consumer (B2C) online goods retail, online retail, e-tail, e-retail and e-commerce markets are used synonymously.

In contrast to classical quantity-based revenue management, dynamic pricing, also known as surge pricing, is the practice of adjusting prices according to current market demand (Boer 2015a ). Revenue management, also known as yield management, is a type of price discrimination which originates from the airline and hospitality industries. Typically, revenue management models assume fixed capacities, low marginal cost, varying demand and highly perishable inventory (Talluri and van Ryzin 2004 ).

Keywords used for abstract, title and keyword screening were “competitive pricing”, “competitor-based pricing”, “competition” AND “pricing”. To find literature for online pricing in particular, the search was combined with the keywords “online”, “e-retail”, “ecommerce” and “e-commerce”. Whereas the combination was scanned in great depths, the three competitive keywords were screened for influential papers with implications for online markets.

Bertrand competition is a simplified model of competition to explain price competition among (at least) two firms for an identical product at equal unit cost of production. Prices are set simultaneously, and consumers buy without search costs from the firm with the lowest price. When all firms charge the same price, consumer demand is split evenly between firms. A firm is willing to supply unlimited amounts of quantities above the unit cost of production and is indifferent to supply at unit cost as it will earn zero profit. The only Bertrand equilibrium exists when prices are equal to unit cost (i.e., competitive price) as each firm otherwise would have an incentive to undercut all other competitors and thereby rake in the entire market demand. Therefore, there can be no equilibrium at prices above the competitive price and price dispersion cannot occur.

In vertical differentiation, consumer choice depends on specific quality levels of product attributes. At the same price, all consumers prefer one product over other products, for example because of superior design. In the simplest form, products differ in one attribute and customers are willing to pay marginal increments of this attribute.

In horizontal differentiation, consumer choice depends on preferences for products. At the same price, some customers would buy one product and others other products.

We consider product differentiation only to product-related differentiation attributes. However, in competitive pricing literature firm-related differences such as firm loyalty or distribution channels are occasionally attributed to differentiation. For example, Abhishek et al. ( 2016 ) differentiate online distribution channels of otherwise homogeneous products and firms.

Heterogeneous customer preferences are a key requirement for product differentiation, otherwise price constitutes the only driver of the buying decision (Li et al. 2017 ). Without heterogeneity in consumers’ marginal willingness to pay for different levels of product quality, there can be no product differentiation (Pigou 1920 ).

Accessed 14–03-2022.

Salvage value is defined as the residual cash-flow of a good after its expiration date.

For example, game settings on the foundation of Stackelberg games necessarily comprise ≥ 2 stages (Geng and Mallik 2007 ; Gupta et al.; Wang et al. 2020 ; Yao and Liu 2005 ). Another example would be Anand and Girotra ( 2007 ) who propose a 3-stage model in which they include the supply chain configuration and determination of production quantities in addition to the actual price setting.

As such, we classify n-stage models as dynamic models when not all individual stages serve a specific time-independent purpose.

For instance, the Brandenburg consumer advice center (Verbraucherzentrale Brandenburg) examined dynamic price differentiation in online retail and found that 15 of the 16 observed German online shops dynamically changed their prices in 2018 (Dautzenberg et al. 2018 ).

A typical rule would be to set prices always x% lower than competitor prices up to a certain profit threshold.

Observable market data include price and stock levels of competitors (Fisher et al. 2018 ) or clickstream and keyword data of customers (Li et al. 2017 ).

Examples for support programs by online marketplaces are Amazon’s Seller Central ( https://sellercentral.amazon.com/gp/help/external/G201994820?language=en_US&ref=efph_G201994820_cont_43381 ; Accessed 14–03-2022), eBay’s Seller Tools ( https://pages.ebay.com/sell/automation.html ; Accessed 14–03-2022) or Idealo’s Partner Program ( https://partner.idealo.com/de ; Accessed 14–03-2022).

Cumulatively, these values exceed 100% as some articles discussed more than one kind of market structure. Applied by economists to simplify real markets as the foundation of price theory, perfect competition relates to a market structure which is controlled entirely by market forces and not by individual firms. Instead, individual firms only act as price takers and cannot earn any economic profit. The conditions for a perfect competition, such as full information, homogeneous products, fully rational buyers, no scale, network or externality effects, no entry barriers, and no transaction costs, are rarely attainable in practical settings (Stigler 1957 ). If not all conditions for perfect competition are fulfilled, the market structure is imperfect which applies to most practical settings. Besides a monopoly with only one seller on the market, three market structures with competing firms exist: Monopolistic, duopolistic, and oligopolistic competition. An oligopoly is characterized by a small number of firms in which the behavior of one firm drives the actions of other firms. A duopoly is a particular case of an oligopoly in which two firms control the market. An extreme case of imperfect competition is (quasi) monopolistic competition in which products are differentiated and firms maintain a certain spare capacity giving them a certain degree of pricing power to maximize their (short-term) profits. In consequence, prices can be higher than corresponding the competitive (Bertrand) price (Vives 2001 ).

For an overview of the top 15 online shops in the United States in 2021, see Davidkhanian ( 2021 ).

Abhishek, Vibhanshu, Kinshuk Jerath, and Z. John Zhang. 2016. Agency selling or reselling? Channel structures in electronic retailing. Management Science 62 (8): 2259–2280. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2015.2230 .

Article   Google Scholar  

Adida, Elodie, and Georgia Perakis. 2010. Dynamic pricing and inventory control: Uncertainty and competition. Operations Research 58 (2): 289–302. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.1090.0718?journalCode=opre .

Afeche, Philipp, Hu Ming, and Yang Li. 2011. Reorder flexibility and price competition for differentiated seasonal products with market size uncertainty. SSRN Electronic Journal . https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1976886 .

Aggarwal, Praveen, and Taihoon Cha. 1998. Asymmetric price competition and store vs. national brand choice. Journal of Product & Brand Management 7 (3): 244–253. https://doi.org/10.1108/10610429810222877 .

Aksoy-Pierson, Margaret, Gad Allon, and Awi Federgruen. 2013. Price competition under mixed multinomial logit demand functions. Management Science 59 (8): 1817–1835. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1664 .

Allen, Beth, and Martin Hellwig. 1986. Bertrand-Edgeworth oligopoly in large markets. Review of Economic Studies 53 (2): 175–204. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297646 .

Anand, Krishnan S., and Karan Girotra. 2007. The strategic perils of delayed differentiation. Management Science 53 (5): 697–712. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1060.0655 .

Anderson, Eric T., and Nanda Kumar. 2007. Price competition with repeat, loyal buyers. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 5 (4): 333–359. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-007-9023-7 .

Anderson, Chris K., Henning Rasmussen, and Leo MacDonald. 2005. Competitive pricing with dynamic asymmetric price effects. International Transactions in Operational Research 12 (5): 509–525. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-3995.2005.00522.x .

Anton, James J., Gary Biglaiser, and Nikolaos Vettas. 2014. Dynamic price competition with capacity constraints and a strategic buyer. International Economic Review 55 (3): 943–958. https://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12077 .

Anufriev, Mikhail, Dávid Kopányi, and Jan Tuinstra. 2013. Learning cycles in bertrand competition with differentiated commodities and competing learning rules. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 (12): 2562–2581. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2013.06.010 .

Armstrong, J. Scott, and Kesten C. Green. 2007. Competitor-oriented objectives: Myth of market share. International Journal of Business 12 (1): 117–136.

Google Scholar  

Ba, Sulin, Jan Stallaert, and Zhongju Zhang. 2012. Research note—Online price dispersion: A game-theoretic perspective and empirical evidence. Information Systems Research 23 (2): 575–592. https://doi.org/10.1287/isre.1110.0353 .

Babaioff, Moshe, Renato Paes Leme, and Balasubramanian Sivan. 2015. Price competition, fluctuations, and welfare guarantees. In EC '15: Proceedings of the Sixteenth ACM Conference on Economics and Computation, Portland, USA. 15-Jun-15 - 19-Jun-15. https://doi.org/10.48550/arXiv.1411.2036

Balakrishnan, Anantaram, Shankar Sundaresan, and Bo. Zhang. 2014. Browse-and-switch: Retail-online competition under value uncertainty. Production and Operations Management 23 (7): 1129–1145. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12165 .

Balasubramanian, Sridhar. 1998. Mail versus mall: A strategic analysis of competition between direct marketers and conventional retailers. Marketing Science 17 (3): 181–195. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.17.3.181 .

Baloglu, Seyhmus, and Lisa Marie Assante. 1999. A content analysis of subject areas and research methods used in five hospitality management journals. Journal of Hospitality & Tourism Research 23 (1): 53–70. https://doi.org/10.1177/109634809902300105 .

Bernstein, Fernando, and Awi Federgruen. 2004. A general equilibrium model for industries with price and service competition. Operations Research 52 (6): 868–886. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.1040.0149 .

Bernstein, Fernando, and Awi Federgruen. 2005. Decentralized supply chains with competing retailers under demand uncertainty. Management Science 51 (1): 18–29. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1040.0218 .

Bernstein, Fernando, Jing-Sheng Song, and Xiaona Zheng. 2008. “Bricks-and-mortar” vs. “clicks-and-mortar”: An equilibrium analysis. European Journal of Operational Research 187 (3): 671–690. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2006.04.047 .

Bertrand, Joseph Louis François. 1883. Thèorie mathèmatique de la richesse sociale. Journal des Savants 499–508.

Bertsimas, Dimitris, and Georgia Perakis. 2006. Dynamic pricing: A learning approach. In Mathematical and computational models for congestion charging , ed. Siriphong Lawphongpanich, Donald W. Hearn, and Michael J. Smith, 45–79. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

Chapter   Google Scholar  

Besbes, Omar, and Denis Sauré. 2016. Product assortment and price competition under multinomial logit demand. Production and Operations Management 25 (1): 114–127. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12402 .

Bischi, Gian-Italo, Carl Chiarella, and Michael Kopel. 2004. The long run outcomes and global dynamics of a duopoly game with misspecified demand functions. International Game Theory Review 6 (3): 343–379. https://doi.org/10.1142/S0219198904000253 .

Blattberg, Robert C., and Kenneth J. Wisniewski. 1989. Price-induced patterns of competition. Marketing Science 8 (4): 291–309. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.8.4.291 .

Boardman, Rosy, and Helen McCormick. 2018. Shopping channel preference and usage motivations. Journal of Fashion Marketing and Management: An International Journal 22 (2): 270–284. https://doi.org/10.1108/JFMM-04-2017-0036 .

Boccard, Nicolas, and Xavier Wauthy. 2000. Bertrand competition and Cournot outcomes: Further results. Economics Letters 68 (3): 279–285. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1765(00)00256-1 .

Borenstein, Severin, and L. Rose Nancy. 1994. Competition and price dispersion in the U.S. airline industry. Journal of Political Economy 102 (4): 653–683. https://doi.org/10.1086/261950 .

Borsenberger, Claire. 2015. The concentration phenomenon in e-commerce. In Postal and delivery innovation in the digital economy , ed. Michael A. Crew and Timothy J. Brennan, 31–41. Cham: Springer International Publishing.

Boyd, E. Andrew, and Ioana C. Bilegan. 2003. Revenue management and e-commerce. Management Science 49 (10): 1363–1386. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.49.10.1363.17316 .

Bresnahan, Timothy F., and Peter C. Reiss. 1991. Entry and competition in concentrated markets. Journal of Political Economy 99 (5): 977–1009. https://doi.org/10.1086/261786 .

Brown, Jeffrey R., and Austan Goolsbee. 2002. Does the internet make markets more competitive? Evidence from the life insurance industry. Journal of Political Economy 110 (3): 481–507. https://doi.org/10.1086/339714 .

Bryant, John. 1980. Competitive equilibrium with price setting firms and stochastic demand. International Economic Review 21 (3): 619–626. https://doi.org/10.2307/2526357 .

Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Michael D. Smith. 2000. Frictionless commerce? A comparison of internet and conventional retailers. Management Science 46 (4): 563–585. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.46.4.563.12061 .

Cachon, Gérard P., and Pnina Feldman. 2010. Dynamic versus static pricing in the presence of strategic consumers. The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania (Working Paper).

Cachon, Gérard. P., and Patrick T. Harker. 2002. Competition and outsourcing with scale economies. Management Science 48 (10): 1314–1333. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.48.10.1314.271 .

Caillaud, Bernard, and Romain de Nijs. 2014. Strategic loyalty reward in dynamic price discrimination. Marketing Science 33 (5): 725–742. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2013.0840 .

Calvano, Emilio, Giacomo Calzolari, Vincenzo Denicolò, and Sergio Pastorello. 2020. Artificial intelligence, algorithmic pricing, and collusion. American Economic Review 110 (10): 3267–3297. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20190623 .

Campbell, Colin, Gautam Ray, and Waleed A. Muhanna. 2005. Search and collusion in electronic markets. Management Science 51 (3): 497–507. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1040.0327 .

Cao, Yong, and Thomas S. Gruca. 2003. The effect of stock market dynamics on internet price competition. Journal of Service Research 6 (1): 24–36. https://doi.org/10.1177/1094670503254272 .

Caplin, Andrew, and Barry Nalebuff. 1991. Aggregation and imperfect competition: On the existence of equilibrium. Econometrica 59 (1): 25–59. https://doi.org/10.2307/2938239 .

Caro, Felipe. 2012. Zara: Staying fast and fresh. The European Case Clearing House. ECCH Case study 612-006-1.

Caro, Felipe, and Jérémie. Gallien. 2012. Clearance pricing optimization for a fast-fashion retailer. Operations Research 60 (6): 1404–1422. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1731402 .

Cattani, Kyle, Olga Perdikaki, and Ann Marucheck. 2007. The perishability of online grocers. Decision Sciences 38 (2): 329–355. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5915.2007.00161.x .

Cavallo, Alberto. 2018. More Amazon effects: online competition and pricing behaviors. National Bureau of Economic Research (Working Papers 25138).

Cebollada, Javier, Yanlai Chu, and Zhiying Jiang. 2019. Online category pricing at a multichannel grocery retailer. Journal of Interactive Marketing 46 (1): 52–69. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intmar.2018.12.004 .

Chen, Yongmin. 1997. Paying customers to switch. Journal of Economics Management Strategy 6 (4): 877–897. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1430-9134.1997.00877.x .

Chen, Ming, and Zhi-Long. Chen. 2015. Recent developments in dynamic pricing research: Multiple products, competition, and limited demand information. Production and Operations Management 24 (5): 704–731. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12295 .

Chen, Yongmin, and Michael H. Riordan. 2008. Price-increasing competition. RAND Journal of Economics 39 (4): 1042–1058. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1756-2171.2008.00049.x .

Chen, Ying-Ju, Yves Zenou, and Junjie Zhou. 2018. Competitive pricing strategies in social networks. RAND Journal of Economics 49 (3): 672–705. https://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12249 .

Cheng, Kuangnen. 2017. Competitive dynamics across strategic groups: A literature review and validation by quantitative evidence of operation data. International Journal of Business Environment 9 (4): 301–323. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJBE.2017.092223 .

Chiang, Wen Chyuan, Jason C.H. Chen, and Xu Xiaojing. 2007. An overview of research on revenue management: Current issues and future research. International Journal of Revenue Management 1 (1): 97–128. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJRM.2007.011196 .

Chintagunta, Pradeep K., Junhong Chu, and Javier Cebollada. 2012. Quantifying transaction costs in online/offline grocery channel choice. Marketing Science 31 (1): 96–114. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1110.0678 .

Chioveanu, Ioana. 2012. Price and quality competition. Journal of Economics 107 (1): 23–44. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-011-0259-z .

Chioveanu, Ioana, and Jidong Zhou. 2013. Price competition with consumer confusion. Management Science 59 (11): 2450–2469. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2013.1716 .

Choi, S. Chan. 1996. Price competition in a duopoly common retailer channel. Journal of Retailing 72 (2): 117–134. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-4359(96)90010-X .

Christen, Markus. 2005. Research note: Cost uncertainty is bliss: The effect of competition on the acquisition of cost information for pricing new products. Management Science 51 (4): 668–676. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1040.0320 .

Chu, Junhong, Pradeep Chintagunta, and Javier Cebollada. 2008. Research note: A comparison of within-household price sensitivity across online and offline channels. Marketing Science 27 (2): 283–299. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1070.0288 .

Chung, Byung Sun, Jiahan Li, Tao Yao, Changhyun Kwon, and Terry L. Friesz. 2012. Demand learning and dynamic pricing under competition in a state-space framework. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management 59 (2): 240–249.

Clemons, Eric K., Il-Horn Hann, and Lorin M. Hitt. 2002. Price dispersion and differentiation in online travel: An empirical investigation. Management Science 48 (4): 534–549. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.48.4.534 .

Cooper, William L., Tito Homem-de-Mello, and Anton J. Kleywegt. 2015. Learning and pricing with models that do not explicitly incorporate competition. Operations Research 63 (1): 86–103. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.2014.1341 .

Currie, Christine S. M., Russell C. H. Cheng, and Honora K. Smith. 2008. Dynamic pricing of airline tickets with competition. Journal of the Operational Research Society 59 (8): 1026–1037. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jors.2602425 .

Dana, James D., and Nicholas C. Petruzzi. 2001. Note: The newsvendor model with endogenous demand. Management Science 47 (11): 1488–1497. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.47.11.1488.10252 .

Dana, James D., and Kevin R. Williams. 2022. Intertemporal price discrimination in sequential quantity-price games. Marketing Science . https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2021.1345 .

Dasci, Abdullah, and Mustafa Karakul. 2009. Two-period dynamic versus fixed-ratio pricing in a capacity constrained duopoly. European Journal of Operational Research 197 (3): 945–968. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2007.12.039 .

Dautzenberg, Kirsti, Constanze Gaßmann, and Britta Groß. 2018. Online-Handel: Das Spiel mit dem dynamischen Preis. https://www.verbraucherzentrale-brandenburg.de/sites/default/files/2018-08/marktwaechter-untersuchung-dynamische-preisdifferenzierung.pdf . Accessed 14 March 2022.

Davidkhanian, Suzy. 2021. US retail spending jumped nearly 16% this year despite inflation, supply chain woes. https://www.emarketer.com/content/us-retail-spending-jumped-this-year-despite-inflation-supply-chain-woes . Accessed 14 March 2022.

de Toni, Deonir, Gabriel Sperandio Milan, Evandro Busata Saciloto, and Fabiano Larentis. 2017. Pricing strategies and levels and their impact on corporate profitability. Revista de Administração 52 (2): 120–133. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rausp.2016.12.004 .

Deck, Cary, and Gu Jingping. 2012. Price increasing competition? Experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 84 (3): 730–740. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2012.09.015 .

den Boer, Arnoud V. 2015a. Dynamic pricing and learning: Historical origins, current research, and new directions. Surveys in Operations Research and Management Science 20 (1): 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.sorms.2015.03.001 .

den Boer, Arnoud V. 2015b. Tracking the market: Dynamic pricing and learning in a changing environment. European Journal of Operational Research 247 (3): 914–927.

DeSarbo, Wayne S., and Rajdeep Grewal. 2007. An alternative efficient representation of demand-based competitive asymmetry. Strategic Management Journal 28 (7): 755–766. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.601 .

Devaraj, Sarv, Ming Fan, and Rajiv Kohli. 2002. Antecedents of B2C channel satisfaction and preference: Validating e-commerce metrics. Information Systems Research 13 (3): 316–333. https://doi.org/10.1287/isre.13.3.316.77 .

Diamond, Peter A. 1971. A model of price adjustment. Journal of Economic Theory 3 (2): 156–168. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-0531(71)90013-5 .

Dickson, Peter R., and Joel E. Urbany. 1994. Retailer reactions to competitive price changes. Journal of Retailing 70 (1): 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-4359(94)90025-6 .

Dinerstein, Michael, Liran Einav, Jonathan Levin, and Neel Sundaresan. 2018. Consumer price search and platform design in internet commerce. American Economic Review 108 (7): 1820–1859. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20171218 .

Dong, James, A. Serdar Simsek, and Huseyin Topaloglu. 2019. Pricing problems under the Markov chain choice model. Production and Operations Management 28 (1): 157–175. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12903 .

Dudey, Marc. 1992. Dynamic Edgeworth-Bertrand competition. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107 (4): 1461–1477. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118397 .

Dzyabura, Daria, Srikanth Jagabathula, and Eitan Muller. 2019. Accounting for discrepancies between online and offline product evaluations. Marketing Science 38 (1): 88–106. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2018.1124 .

Elmaghraby, Wedad, and Pınar Keskinocak. 2003. Dynamic pricing in the presence of inventory considerations: Research overview, current practices, and future directions. Management Science 49 (10): 1287–1309. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.49.10.1287.17315 .

Farias, Vivek, Denis Saure, and Gabriel Y. Weintraub. 2012. An approximate dynamic programming approach to solving dynamic oligopoly models. RAND Journal of Economics 43 (2): 253–282. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1756-2171.2012.00165.x .

Fay, Scott. 2008. Selling an opaque product through an intermediary: The case of disguising one’s product. Journal of Retailing 84 (1): 59–75. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2008.01.005 .

Federgruen, Awi, and Hu Ming. 2015. Multi-product price and assortment competition. Operations Research 63 (3): 572–584. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.2015.1380 .

Ferreira, Kris Johnson, Bin Hong Alex. Lee, and David Simchi-Levi. 2016. Analytics for an online retailer: Demand forecasting and price optimization. Manufacturing Service Operations Management 18 (1): 69–88. https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2015.0561 .

Fisher, Marshall, Santiago Gallino, and Jun Li. 2018. Competition-based dynamic pricing in online retailing: A methodology validated with field experiments. Management Science 64 (6): 2473–2972. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2017.2753 .

Frambach, Ruud T., Henk C.A. Roest, and Trichy V. Krishnan. 2007. The impact of consumer internet experience on channel preference and usage intentions across the different stages of the buying process. Journal of Interactive Marketing 21 (2): 26–41. https://doi.org/10.1002/dir.20079 .

Gallego, Guillermo, and Hu Ming. 2014. Dynamic pricing of perishable assets under competition. Management Science 60 (5): 1241–1259. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2013.1821 .

Gallego, Guillermo, Woonghee Tim Huh, Wanmo Kang, and Robert Phillips. 2006. Price competition with the attraction demand model: Existence of unique equilibrium and its stability. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 8 (4): 359–375. https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.1060.0115 .

Gallego, Guillermo, and Garrett J. van Ryzin. 1997. A multiproduct dynamic pricing problem and its applications to network yield management. Operations Research 45 (1): 24–41. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.45.1.24 .

Gallego, Guillermo, and Ruxian Wang. 2014. Multi-product optimization and competition under the nested logit model with product-differentiated price sensitivities. Operations Research 62 (2): 450–461. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.2013.1249 .

Gao, Fei, and Su Xuanming. 2018. Omnichannel service operations with online and offline self-order technologies. Management Science 64 (8): 3595–3608. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2017.2787 .

Geng, Qin, and Suman Mallik. 2007. Inventory competition and allocation in a multi-channel distribution system. European Journal of Operational Research 182 (2): 704–729. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2006.08.041 .

Gönsch, Jochen, Robert Klein, and Claudius Steinhardt. 2009. Dynamic pricing - State-of-the-art. Journal of Business Economics 3 (2): 1–40.

Gupta, Varun, Dmitry Ivanov, and Tsan-Ming Choi. 2021. Competitive pricing of substitute products under supply disruption. Omega . https://doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2020.102279 .

Hagiu, Andrei. 2007. Merchant or two-sided platform? Review of Network Economics 6 (2): 115–133. https://doi.org/10.2202/1446-9022.1113 .

Hall, Joseph M., Praveen K. Kopalle, and David F. Pyke. 2009. Static and dynamic pricing of excess capacity in a make-to-order environment. Production and Operations Management 18 (4): 411–425. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1937-5956.2009.01044.x .

Hamilton, Jonathan H., and Steven M. Slutsky. 1990. Endogenous timing in duopoly games: Stackelberg or cournot equilibria. Games and Economic Behavior 2 (1): 29–46. https://doi.org/10.1016/0899-8256(90)90012-J .

Harsha, Pavithra, Shivaram Subramanian, and Joline Uichanco. 2019. Dynamic pricing of omnichannel inventories. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management 21 (1): 47–65. https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2018.0737 .

Heese, H. Sebastian, and Victor Martínez-de-Albéniz. 2018. Effects of assortment breadth announcements on manufacturer competition. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management 20 (2): 302–316. https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2017.0643 .

Hinterhuber, Andreas. 2008. Customer value-based pricing strategies: Why companies resist. Journal of Business Strategy 29 (4): 41–50. https://doi.org/10.1108/02756660810887079 .

Isler, Karl, and Henrik Imhof. 2008. A game theoretic model for airline revenue management and competitive pricing. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management 7 (4): 384–396. https://doi.org/10.1057/rpm.2008.30 .

Israeli, Ayelet, Fiona Scott-Morton, Jorge Silva-Risso, and Florian Zettelmeyer. 2022. How market power affects dynamic pricing: Evidence from inventory fluctuations at car dealerships. Management Science 68 (2): 895–916. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2021.3967 .

Ittoo, Ashwin, and Nicolas Petit. 2017. Algorithmic pricing agents and tacit collusion: A technological perspective. SSRN Electronic Journal . https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3046405 .

Janssen, Maarten C. W., and José Luis Moraga-González. 2004. Strategic pricing, consumer search and the number of firms. Review of Economic Studies 71 (4): 1089–1118. https://doi.org/10.1111/0034-6527.00315 .

Jerath, Kinshuk, Serguei Netessine, and Senthil K. Veeraraghavan. 2010. Revenue management with strategic customers: Last-minute selling and opaque selling. Management Science 56 (3): 430–448. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1090.1125 .

Kachani, Shmatov, Soulaymane Kachani, and Kyrylo Shmatov. 2010. Competitive pricing in a multi-product multi-attribute environment. Production and Operations Management 20 (5): 668–680. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1937-5956.2010.01195.x .

Kastius, Alexander, and Rainer Schlosser. 2022. Dynamic pricing under competition using reinforcement learning. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management 21 (1): 50–63. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-021-00285-3 .

Keskin, N. Bora, and Assaf Zeevi. 2017. Chasing demand: Learning and earning in a changing environment. Mathematics of Operations Research 42 (2): 277–307. https://doi.org/10.1287/moor.2016.0807 .

Kim, Jun B., Paulo Albuquerque, and Bart J. Bronnenberg. 2011. Mapping online consumer search. Journal of Marketing Research 48 (1): 13–27. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.48.1.13 .

Koças, Cenk. 2005. A model of internet pricing under price-comparison shopping. International Journal of Electronic Commerce 10 (1): 111–134. https://doi.org/10.1080/10864415.2005.11043959 .

Könönen, Ville. 2006. Dynamic pricing based on asymmetric multiagent reinforcement learning. International Journal of Intelligent Systems 21 (1): 73–98. https://doi.org/10.1002/int.20121 .

Kopalle, Praveen, Dipayan Biswas, Pradeep K. Chintagunta, Jia Fan, Koen Pauwels, Brian T. Ratchford, and James A. Sills. 2009. Retailer pricing and competitive effects. Journal of Retailing 85 (1): 56–70. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretai.2008.11.005 .

Kutschinski, Erich, Thomas Uthmann, and Daniel Polani. 2003. Learning competitive pricing strategies by multi-agent reinforcement learning. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27 (11): 2207–2218. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1889(02)00122-7 .

Lal, Rajiv, and Ram Rao. 1997. Supermarket competition: The case of every day low pricing. Marketing Science 16 (1): 60–80. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.16.1.60 .

Lal, Rajiv, and Miklos Sarvary. 1999. When and how is the internet likely to decrease price competition? Marketing Science 18 (4): 485–503. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.18.4.485 .

Lancaster, Kelvin. 1979. Variety, equity, and efficiency: Product variety in an industrial society . New York: Columbia University Press.

Book   Google Scholar  

Larson, Ronald B. 2019. Promoting demand-based pricing. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management 18 (1): 42–51. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-017-0126-9 .

Le Chen, Alan Mislove, and Christo Wilson. 2016. An empirical analysis of algorithmic pricing on Amazon Marketplace. In Proceedings of the 25th International Conference on World Wide Web - WWW '16 , 1339–1349, Montreal. 11-Apr-16 - 15-Apr-16. New York: ACM Press. https://doi.org/10.1145/2872427.2883089

Lebow, Sara. 2019. Worldwide ecommerce continues double-digit growth following pandemic push to online. https://www.emarketer.com/content/worldwide-ecommerce-continues-double-digit-growth-following-pandemic-push-online . Accessed 14 March 2022.

Lee, Khai Sheang, and Soo Jiuan Tan. 2003. E-retailing versus physical retailing. A theoretical model and empirical test of consumer choice. Journal of Business Research 56 (11): 877–885. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0148-2963(01)00274-0 .

Lee, Thomas Y., and Eric T. Bradlow. 2011. Automated marketing research using online customer reviews. Journal of Marketing Research 48 (5): 881–894. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.48.5.881 .

Levin, Yuri, Jeff McGill, and Mikhail Nediak. 2008. Risk in revenue management and dynamic pricing. Operations Research 56 (2): 326–343. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.1070.0438 .

Levin, Yuri, Jeff McGill, and Mikhail Nediak. 2009. Dynamic pricing in the presence of strategic consumers and oligopolistic competition. Management Science 55: 32–46. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1080.0936 .

Li, Jun, Serguei Netessine, and Sergei Koulayev. 2017. Price to compete… with many: How to identify price competition in high-dimensional space. Management Science 64 (9): 4118–4136. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2017.2820 .

Li, Michael Z. F., Anming Zhang, and Yimin Zhang. 2008. Airline seat allocation competition. International Transactions in Operational Research 15 (4): 439–459. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-3995.2008.00642.x .

Lin, Yen-Ting, Ali K. Parlaktürk, and Jayashankar M. Swaminathan. 2014. Vertical integration under competition: Forward, backward, or no integration? Production and Operations Management 23 (1): 19–35. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12030 .

Lin, Kyle Y., and Soheil Y. Sibdari. 2009. Dynamic price competition with discrete customer choices. European Journal of Operational Research 197 (3): 969–980. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2007.12.040 .

Liozu, Stephan. 2015. The pricing journey: The organizational transformation toward pricing excellence . Stanford: Stanford Business Books.

Lippman, Steven A., and Kevin F. McCardle. 1997. The competitive newsboy. Operations Research 45 (1): 54–65. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.45.1.54 .

Liu, Qian, and Dan Zhang. 2013. Dynamic pricing competition with strategic customers under vertical product differentiation. Management Science 59 (1): 84–101. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1564 .

Loginova, Oksana. 2021. Price competition online: Platforms versus branded websites. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy . https://doi.org/10.1111/jems.12461 .

Mantin, Benny, Daniel Granot, and Frieda Granot. 2011. Dynamic pricing under first order Markovian competition. Naval Research Logistics 58 (6): 608–617. https://doi.org/10.1002/nav.20470 .

Martínez-de-Albéniz, Victor, and Kalyan Talluri. 2011. Dynamic price competition with fixed capacities. Management Science 57 (6): 1078–1093. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1337 .

Maskin, Eric, and Jean Tirole. 1988. A theory of dynamic oligopoly, II: Price competition, kinked demand curves, and edgeworth cycles. Econometrica 56 (3): 571–599. https://doi.org/10.2307/1911701 .

Matsubayashi, Nobuo, and Yoshiyasu Yamada. 2008. A note on price and quality competition between asymmetric firms. European Journal of Operational Research 187 (2): 571–581. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2007.03.021 .

McGill, Jeffrey I., and Garrett J. van Ryzin. 1999. Revenue management: Research overview and prospects. Transportation Science 33 (2): 233–256. https://doi.org/10.1287/trsc.33.2.233 .

Miklós-Thal, Jeanine, and Catherine Tucker. 2019. Collusion by algorithm: Does better demand prediction facilitate coordination between sellers? Management Science 65 (4): 1552–1561. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2019.3287 .

Mitra, Subrata. 2021. Economic models of price competition between traditional and online retailing under showrooming. Decision . https://doi.org/10.1007/s40622-021-00293-7 .

Mizuno, Toshihide. 2003. On the existence of a unique price equilibrium for models of product differentiation. International Journal of Industrial Organization 21 (6): 761–793. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-7187(03)00017-1 .

Mookherjee, Reetabrata, and Terry L. Friesz. 2008. Pricing, allocation, and overbooking in dynamic service network competition when demand is uncertain. Production and Operations Management 17 (4): 455–474. https://doi.org/10.3401/poms.1080.0042 .

Moorthy, K. Sridhar. 1988. Product and price competition in a duopoly. Marketing Science 7 (2): 141–168. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.7.2.141 .

Motta, Massimo. 1993. Endogenous quality choice: Price vs. quantity competition. The Journal of Industrial Economics 41 (2): 113–131. https://doi.org/10.2307/2950431 .

Nalca, Arcan, Tamer Boyaci, and Saibal Ray. 2010. Competitive price-matching guarantees under imperfect store availability. Quantitative Marketing and Economics 8 (3): 275–300. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11129-010-9080-1 .

Netessine, Serguei, and Robert A. Shumsky. 2005. Revenue management games: Horizontal and vertical competition. Management Science 51 (5): 813–831. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1040.0356 .

Netzer, Oded, Ronen Feldman, Jacob Goldenberg, and Moshe Fresko. 2012. Mine your own business: Market-structure surveillance through text mining. Marketing Science 31 (3): 521–543. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1120.0713 .

Nip, Kameng, Changjun Wang, and Zizhuo Wang. 2020. Competitive and cooperative assortment games under Markov chain choice model. SSRN Electronic Journal . https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3607722 .

Noel, Michael D. 2007. Edgeworth price cycles, cost-based pricing, and sticky pricing in retail gasoline markets. Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (2): 324–334. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest.89.2.324 .

Obermeyer, Andy, Christos Evangelinos, and Ronny Püschel. 2013. Price dispersion and competition in European airline markets. Journal of Air Transport Management 26 (1): 31–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jairtraman.2012.08.014 .

Olivares, Marcelo, and Gérard. P. Cachon. 2009. Competing retailers and inventory: An empirical investigation of General Motors’ dealerships in isolated U.S. markets. Management Science 55 (9): 1586–1604. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1090.1050 .

Parlar, Mahmut. 1988. Game theoretic analysis of the substitutable product inventory problem with random demands. Naval Research Logistics 35 (3): 397–409. https://doi.org/10.1002/1520-6750(198806)35:3%3c397:AID-NAV3220350308%3e3.0.CO;2-Z .

Penz, Elfriede, and Margaret K. Hogg. 2011. The role of mixed emotions in consumer behaviour. European Journal of Marketing 45 (1): 104–132. https://doi.org/10.1108/03090561111095612 .

Perakis, Georgia, and Anshul Sood. 2006. Competitive multi-period pricing for perishable products: A robust optimization approach. Mathematical Programming 107 (1–2): 295–335. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10107-005-0688-y .

Perloff, Jeffrey M., and Steven C. Salop. 1985. Equilibrium with product differentiation. Review of Economic Studies 52 (1): 107. https://doi.org/10.2307/2297473 .

Phillips, Robert L. 2021. Pricing and revenue optimization , 2nd ed. Stanford: Stanford Business Books.

Pigou, Arthur Cecil. 1920. The economics of welfare . London: Macmillan & co.

Popescu, Dana. 2015. Repricing algorithms in e-commerce. Technology and Operations Management (Working Paper No. 2015/75/TOM). https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2669997 .

Putsis, William, and Ravi Dhar. 1998. The many faces of competition. Marketing Letters 9 (3): 269–284. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1008072222645 .

Ratchford, Brian T. 2009. Online pricing: Review and directions for research. Journal of Interactive Marketing 23 (1): 82–90. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intmar.2008.11.001 .

Richards, Timothy J., and Stephen F. Hamilton. 2006. Rivalry in price and variety among supermarket retailers. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 88 (3): 710–726. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8276.2006.00890.x .

Ringel, Daniel M., and Bernd Skiera. 2016. Visualizing asymmetric competition among more than 1,000 products using big search data. Marketing Science 35 (3): 511–534. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2015.0950 .

Ryan, Jennifer K., Daewon Sun, and Xuying Zhao. 2012. Competition and coordination in online marketplaces. Production and Operations Management 21 (6): 997–1014. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1937-5956.2012.01332.x .

Salop, Steven C. 1976. Information and monopolistic competition. American Economic Review 66 (2): 240–245.

Sarkar, Amit, and Brojeswar Pal. 2021. Competitive pricing strategies of multi channel supply chain under direct servicing by the manufacturer. RAIRO Operations Research 55 (1): 1849–1873. https://doi.org/10.1051/ro/2020063 .

Scarpi, Daniele, Gabriele Pizzi, and Marco Visentin. 2014. Shopping for fun or shopping to buy: Is it different online and offline? Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services 21 (3): 258–267. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jretconser.2014.02.007 .

Schinkel, Maarten Pieter, Jan Tuinstra, and Dries Vermeulen. 2002. Convergence of Bayesian learning to general equilibrium in mis-specified models. Journal of Mathematical Economics 38 (4): 483–508. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4068(02)00062-9 .

Schlereth, Christian, Bernd Skiera, and Fabian Schulz. 2018. Why do consumers prefer static instead of dynamic pricing plans? An empirical study for a better understanding of the low preferences for time-variant pricing plans. European Journal of Operational Research 269 (3): 1165–1179. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2018.03.033 .

Schlosser, Rainer, and Martin Boissier. 2018. Dealing with the dimensionality curse in dynamic pricing competition: Using frequent repricing to compensate imperfect market anticipations. Computers and Operations Research 100: 26–42. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cor.2018.07.011 .

Schlosser, Rainer, Martin Boissier, Andre Schober, and Matthias Uflacker. 2016. How to survive dynamic pricing competition in e-commerce. In Proceedings of the 10th ACM conference on recommender systems, Boston. 15-Sept-16 to 19-Sept-16. New York: Association for Computing Machinery.

Schlosser, Rainer, and Keven Richly. 2019. Dynamic pricing under competition with data-driven price anticipations and endogenous reference price effects. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management 18: 451–464. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-019-00206-5 .

Serth, Sebastian, Nikolai Podlesney, Marvin Bornstein, Jan Lindemann, Johanna Lattt, Jan Selke, Rainer Schlosser, Martin Boissier, and Matthias Uflacker. 2017. An interactive platform to simulate dynamic pricing competition on online marketplaces. In IEEE 21st International Enterprise Distributed Object Computing Conference , 61–66, Quebec City, Canada. 10-Oct-17 to 13-Oct-17. https://doi.org/10.1109/EDOC.2017.17 .

Shugan, Steven M. 2002. Editorial: Marketing science, models, monopoly models, and why we need them. Marketing Science 21 (3): 223–228. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.21.3.223.145 .

Siegert, Caspar, and Robert Ulbricht. 2020. Dynamic oligopoly pricing: Evidence from the airline industry. International Journal of Industrial Organization 71: 102639. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2020.102639 .

Simon, Hermann. 1979. Dynamics of price elasticity and brand life cycles: An empirical study. Journal of Marketing Research 16 (4): 439–452. https://doi.org/10.1177/002224377901600401 .

Smith, Michael D., and Erik Brynjolfsson. 2001. Consumer decision-making at an internet shopbot: Brand still matters. The Journal of Industrial Economics 49 (4): 541–558. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6451.00162 .

Stigler, George J. 1957. Perfect competition, historically contemplated. Journal of Political Economy 65 (1): 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1086/257878 .

Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1979. Equilibrium in product markets with imperfect information. American Economic Review 69 (2): 339–345.

Sun, Haoying, and Stephen M. Gilbert. 2019. Retail price competition with product fit uncertainty and assortment selection. Production and Operations Management 28 (7): 1658–1673. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.13005 .

Talluri, Kalyan T., and Garrett J. van Ryzin. 2004. The theory and practice of revenue management . Boston: Springer.

Thomadsen, Raphael. 2007. Product positioning and competition: The role of location in the fast food industry. Marketing Science 26 (6): 792–804. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1070.0296 .

Tranfield, David, David Denyer, and Palminder Smart. 2003. Towards a methodology for developing evidence-informed management knowledge by means of systematic review. British Journal of Management 14 (3): 207–222. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8551.00375 .

Tuinstra. 2004. A price adjustment process in a model of monopolistic competition. International Game Theory Review 6 (3): 417–442. https://doi.org/10.1142/S0219198904000289 .

van de Geer, Ruben, Arnoud V. den Boer, Christopher Bayliss, Christine S. M. Currie, Andria Ellina, Malte Esders, Alwin Haensel, Xiao Lei, Kyle D. S. Maclean, Antonio Martinez-Sykora, Asbjørn Nilsen Riseth, Fredrik Ødegaard, and Simos Zachariades. 2019. Dynamic pricing and learning with competition: Insights from the dynamic pricing challenge at the 2017 INFORMS RM and pricing conference. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management 18 (3): 185–203. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-018-00164-4 .

van Mieghem, Jan A., and Maqbool Dada. 1999. Price versus production postponement: Capacity and competition. Management Science 45 (12): 1639–1649. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.45.12.1631 .

Villas-Boas, J. Miguel. 1999. Dynamic competition with customer recognition. RAND Journal of Economics 30 (4): 604–631. https://doi.org/10.2307/2556067 .

Villas-Boas, J. Miguel. 2004. Consumer learning, brand loyalty, and competition. Marketing Science 23 (1): 134–145. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1030.0044 .

Villas-Boas, J. Miguel. 2006. Dynamic competition with experience goods. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 15 (1): 37–66. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1530-9134.2006.00091.x .

Villas-Boas, J. Miguel, and Russell S. Winer. 1999. Endogeneity in brand choice models. Management Science 45 (10): 1324–1338. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.45.10.1324 .

Vinod, Balakrishna. 2020. Advances in revenue management: The last frontier. Journal of Revenue and Pricing Management 20: 15–20. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-020-00264-0 .

Viswanathan, Siva. 2005. Competing across technology-differentiated channels: The impact of network externalities and switching costs. Management Science 51 (3): 483–496. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1040.0338 .

Vives, Xavier. 2001. Oligopoly pricing: Old ideas and new tools . London: MIT Press.

von Stackelberg, Heinrich. 2011. Market structure and equilibrium . Berlin: Springer.

Wang, Zizhuo, and Hu Ming. 2014. Committed versus contingent pricing under competition. Production and Operations Management 23 (11): 1919–1936. https://doi.org/10.1111/poms.12202 .

Wang, Sujuan, Hu Qiying, and Liu Weiqi. 2017. Price and quality-based competition and channel structure with consumer loyalty. European Journal of Operational Research 262 (2): 563–574. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2017.03.052 .

Wang, Yongzhao, and Xiaojie Sun. 2019. Dynamic vs. static wholesale pricing strategies in a dual-channel green supply chain. Complexity 13: 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1155/2019/8497070 .

Wang, Ningning, Ting Zhang, Xiaowei Zhu, and Peimiao Li. 2020. Online-offline competitive pricing with reference price effect. Journal of the Operational Research Society 72 (3): 642–653. https://doi.org/10.1080/01605682.2019.1696154 .

Wang, Wenche, Fan Li, and Yujia Zhang. 2021. Price discount and price dispersion in online market: Do more firms still lead to more competition? Journal of Theoretical and Applied Electronic Commerce Research 16 (2): 164–178. https://doi.org/10.4067/S0718-18762021000200111 .

Weatherford, Lawrence R., and Samuel E. Bodily. 1992. A taxonomy and research overview of perishable-asset revenue management: Yield management, overbooking, and pricing. Operations Research 40 (5): 831–844. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.40.5.831 .

Weintraub, Gabriel Y., C. Lanier Benkard, and Benjamin van Roy. 2008. Markov perfect industry dynamics with many firms. Econometrica 76 (6): 1375–1411. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA6158 .

Wenzelburger, J. 2004. Learning to play best response in duopoly games. International Game Theory Review 6 (3): 443–459. https://doi.org/10.1142/S0219198904000290 .

Won, Eugene J. S., Oh. Yun Kyung, and Joon Yeon Choeh. 2022. Analyzing competitive market structures based on online consumer-generated content and sales data. Asia Pacific Journal of Marketing and Logistics Advance Online Publication . https://doi.org/10.1108/APJML-08-2021-0616 .

Wu, Lin-Liang Bill, and Desheng Wu. 2016. Dynamic pricing and risk analytics under competition and stochastic reference price effects. IEEE Transactions on Industrial Informatics 12 (3): 1282–1293. https://doi.org/10.1109/TII.2015.2507141 .

Xu, Xiaowei, and Wallace J. Hopp. 2006. A monopolistic and oligopolistic stochastic flow revenue management model. Operations Research 54 (6): 1098–1109. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.1060.0336 .

Yang, Jian, and Yusen Xia. 2013. A nonatomic-game approach to dynamic pricing under competition. Production and Operations Management 22 (1): 88–103. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1937-5956.2012.01334.x .

Yang, Yongge, Yu-Ching Lee, and Po-An Chen. 2020. Competitive demand learning: a data-driven pricing algorithm. Cornell University (Working Paper). https://doi.org/10.48550/arxiv.2008.05195 .

Yano, Makoto, and Takashi Komatsubara. 2006. Endogenous price leadership and technological differences. International Journal of Economic Theory 2 (3–4): 365–383. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1742-7363.2006.0041.x .

Yano, Makoto, and Takashi Komatsubara. 2018. Price competition or price leadership. Economic Theory 66 (4): 1023–1057. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-017-1080-x .

Yao, Dong-Qing, and John J. Liu. 2005. Competitive pricing of mixed retail and e-tail distribution channels. Omega 33 (3): 235–247. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2004.04.007 .

Young, Jessica. 2022. US ecommerce grows 14.2% in 2021. https://www.digitalcommerce360.com/article/us-ecommerce-sales/ . Accessed 14 March 2022.

Zhang, Jianxiong, Liyan Lei, Shichen Zhang, and Lijun Song. 2017. Dynamic vs. static pricing in a supply chain with advertising. Computers & Industrial Engineering 109 (1): 266–279. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2017.05.006 .

Zhang, Ting, Ling Ge, Qinglong Gou, and Li-Wen Chen. 2018a. Consumer showrooming, the sunk cost effect and online-offline competition. Journal of Electronic Commerce Research 19 (1): 55–74.

Zhang, Zhichao, Qing Zhang, Zhi Liu, and Xiaoxue Zheng. 2018b. Static and dynamic pricing strategies in a closed-loop supply chain with reference quality effects. Sustainability 10 (1): 157. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10010157 .

Zhao, Xuan, Derek Atkins, Hu Ming, and Wensi Zhang. 2017. Revenue management under joint pricing and capacity allocation competition. European Journal of Operational Research 257 (3): 957–970. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2016.08.025 .

Download references

Open Access funding enabled and organized by Projekt DEAL.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

University of Duisburg-Essen, Duisburg, Germany

Torsten J. Gerpott & Jan Berends

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Torsten J. Gerpott .

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

See Table 4 .

See Table 5 .

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Gerpott, T.J., Berends, J. Competitive pricing on online markets: a literature review. J Revenue Pricing Manag 21 , 596–622 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-022-00390-x

Download citation

Received : 15 March 2022

Accepted : 01 May 2022

Published : 14 June 2022

Issue Date : December 2022

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1057/s41272-022-00390-x

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Competition
  • Competitive pricing
  • Dynamic pricing
  • Online markets
  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research

Business growth

Business tips

A step-by-step guide to competitive market analysis

Hero image with an icon of a magnifying glass (search)

I remember Blockbuster going bankrupt in 2010. As a 12-year-old, this news meant the end of walking down aisles with my family, looking for the perfect weekend flick. But to Netflix, this meant their competitive market analysis had paid off.

As much as I miss my three-day VHS and DVD rentals, video entertainment has improved significantly, thanks to innovation and competitive pressure. Your industry isn't immune to change either, which is why it's so important to get ahead.

Table of contents:

What is a competitive analysis?

The importance of competitive analysis in marketing, how to conduct competitive market analysis in 6 steps, competitive analysis example, internal operations as a competitive advantage.

Competitive market analysis is the process of determining who your competitors are, researching their strategies, and unpacking what they do well (and not so well).

From this process, you can learn a lot about your company's own strengths and weaknesses, as well as how to remain a strong competitor in your industry.

A deep dive into your competitors' strategies will reveal their product offerings, mission statements , target markets, marketing strategies, and more. You may even identify new competitors you didn't know existed.

Identify and fill crucial gaps in your business  

The greats learn from the greats. Yes, you're trying to beat your competitors, but that doesn't mean you can't learn from them—especially if they've been around the block a few times. Seeing what works for your competitors will point toward gaps in your own strategies (as well as gaps in their strategies)—and ideally give you some inspiration on how to fill those gaps.

Spot trends and get ahead

Competitive market analysis isn't just about understanding specific competitors. It can also uncover the direction that an entire industry is moving. For example, Blockbuster didn't move with the industry, and we all know how that ended. Competitive analysis can help you avoid that same fate.

Recognize product value and pain point solutions

By analyzing competitors, you uncover customer pain points they might've missed, allowing you to refine your product's value and directly address those needs. It's not just about watching rivals, but seizing opportunities to stand out.

Set future objectives for growth

By examining market leaders, you define bold markers for your growth, and you can emulate their tactics. You can also employ AI-driven tools like Google Analytics' predictive metrics, HubSpot's forecasting tools, or IBM Watson's analytics. These tools can decipher market patterns, anticipate future prospects, and help you set precise KPIs. With AI's assistance, you can unearth data-driven insights and opportunities even top-tier competitors might miss.

Competitive market analysis isn't just a matter of making sure you have a unique selling point. Here's how to dig into the competition and figure out where you stand—and how to stand out.

1. List your competitors

Start by creating a comprehensive list of everyone operating in your industry. You can weed out the less relevant competitors later, but for now, jot down anyone that offers similar products or services.

If you're a small local business, your competitors are located nearby—you probably know a lot about them, but at the very least, you know they exist. But for something like an eCommerce store or online service, it's important to figure out who your competitors even are.

Start with basic keyword research. Google your product category a few different ways, maybe with words like "price," "cheap," or "sale" to reinforce the commercial nature of your query.

A Google search for "flower shop new york"

This will help you identify any competitors and can shed some light on how saturated your industry is.

Next, categorize the companies you identify into direct and indirect competitors.

Direct competitors provide similar products or services to a target market similar to yours. For example, Gucci and Prada both offer high-end clothing and accessories to fashion-conscious consumers with high disposable income.

Indirect competitors provide different products or services (though ones that land in the same category as yours) to a target market similar to yours. For example, gyms and companies producing at-home workout equipment can be considered indirect competitors.

As the name suggests, direct competitors tend to pose a more direct risk to your business. That said, indirect competitors can still attract customers and pull business away from you. You need to identify and analyze both to truly understand your competitive landscape.

2. Identify their target markets

Sometimes, a competitor's target market is clear—especially if it's a niche brand. Take Dick's Sporting Goods—it's pretty obvious that they're targeting people who are into sports (or who want to be).

For other companies, it isn't as obvious. To determine your competitors' target markets, try the following:

Study their mission statement: Sometimes, a company's mission statement will explicitly state who their products and/or services are designed for. And even when it isn't explicit, it will almost certainly provide a hint. Navigate to the "About" page on their website, and soak up whatever insight you can.

Analyze their voice and tone: Stoic or cheeky? Packed with jargon or written for the novice? Your competitors' tone and wording have a purpose—to get through to their target market. Read company blog posts, join their newsletters, and watch promotional video content, all the while paying close attention to who they seem to be speaking to.

Pay attention to their social media engagement: Observe who comments on their content and how they respond to those comments. The influencers they partner with can also shed light on the audience they want to reach.

3. Unpack their 4 P's

Table showing the four P's of Apple's marketing, product, price, place, and promotion

Competitive market analysis requires you to analyze your competitors' four P's of marketing : product, price, place, and promotion.

The best way to learn about your competitors' customer experiences is to become a customer yourself. You'll gain incredible insights into what's working for them—and more importantly, where there's room to offer something better.

Whenever possible, give your competitors' products a spin. Get a free trial or even buy or sign up for the real deal, if your budget allows. When using their products, try contacting their customer support for additional insight.

Pricing can be one of the most sensitive aspects of marketing. For this reason, you need to understand and track what your competition is doing with their pricing. Here are some questions to ask yourself about each competitor:

What's their pricing model? Subscription-style, one-time purchase, or a mix of both?

Do they seem to be using skim pricing or penetration pricing?

Does their pricing model seem to align with the rest of the industry?

There are many tools out there to help, as well as specialized tools for specific industries, like hotel room price monitoring.

Once you have a grip on your competitors' pricing strategies, here are your options:

Reduce your prices: If pricing is the only differentiator in your industry (meaning product, place, and promotion strategies are all pretty uniform), you may consider lowering your prices to snag a higher share of the market. But be wary about how this will impact customers' perceptions of your quality, as well as the risk of a price reduction competition, driving everyone's prices to unprofitable levels.

Raise your prices: If your business already leads the market by providing something unique or higher-quality products than the competition, you may consider raising your prices. Be mindful of the price elasticity of your product before pursuing this strategy, as a small price increase can lose customers in certain industries.

Match your competitors' pricing: It's much more challenging to sell products at the same price as competitors. This strategy works if your business has been in the market for a while and can make a unique or niche offer. In this case, the customer will decide to purchase based on personal preferences rather than the price.

If you feel like none of the above strategies will work for you, you might explore nontraditional pricing structures like bundling.

Where are your competitors selling? Is everything online, or do they have brick-and-mortar stores?

Every industry trends differently here—shoe brands, for example, tend to have some in-person outlets since most people want to try on a pair of shoes before buying them. Furniture stores, on the other hand, don't always rely on brick-and-mortar locations. They can provide pictures, videos, and product details (such as dimensions and materials) to provide customers with a "good enough" idea of what they're getting.

Promotion encompasses more than just advertising, but since advertising is so measurable and public, it's the easiest to spy on. To avoid wasting your advertising budget , analyze your competitors' strategies.

Here's what you're looking for:

Cost per click: If the CPC is too high, you may not want to use paid ads as a promotion channel at all. It's better to learn this from your competitors than from your own experience.

Keywords: Examine the competition level for each keyword in your competitors' ad campaigns. This will help you find the best-performing keywords with low competition (and that means lower cost per click). You'll also be able to see which keywords aren't doing well and avoid those.

Long-running ads: If your competitor keeps running the same campaign for a long time, it definitely works for them. You can try to create something similar to replicate their success.

If most competitors rely on social media advertisements as opposed to TV or print ads, you should probably follow suit. Likewise, if they're putting their entire budget into advertising how crispy their chicken sandwich is, it's probably because chicken sandwich consumers really like their chicken crispy. Watch how your competitors allocate their advertising budget and use that information to inform your own strategy.

4. Get to know their SEO strategy

SEO is a beast, and there's no surefire way to fully dissect your competitors' strategy. But there are a few ways to at least figure out what's working for them.

Use a keyword research tool to see what topics your competitors are ranking for. Do they rely entirely on industry-specific queries, or do they branch into other tangential topics? What pages are bringing in the most traffic?

By discovering which keywords your competitors target (and rank for), you get insight into what's working for them and uncover new keywords you might have neglected. Even better, you might also find keywords they aren't targeting and identify the underserved customers. You can also use it as a chance to differentiate your message so that you're ranking for more targeted keywords .

The Ahrefs screenshot below shows the highest-traffic-driving pages from Slack's blog. A competing communication platform could use this data to learn what's working for Slack and replicate their success. To really be successful, however, you need to one-up the competition, bringing something new to the table.

Ahrefs screenshot showing the highest-traffic-driving pages from Slack's blog

Ahrefs also lets you see your competitors' backlinks. Figure out which websites are already linking to your competitors, and then you can try to get yourself a backlink from those sites as well.

Pro tip: As you do this research, actually click into some of your competitors' high-ranking pages to see what exactly is attracting users (and Google). Data is crucial, but nothing can replace the human eye.

5. Make note of their most popular content

If you can figure out which types of content—blog posts, videos, podcasts, guides, etc.—are most popular with your competitors' audiences, that can help inform your own content strategy . And here's a tech twist: you can employ ChatGPT to run a content analysis. Simply plug in a piece of content, ask it to run the analysis, and it will quickly dissect the post, highlighting themes, patterns, and potential gaps your brand can capitalize on.

The goal is to identify which content types get the most traffic or engagement. You can use a marketing analytics tool to analyze both of those things:

Do the highest-performing pieces of content tend to all be one specific medium (video, infographic, written content, or something else)?

Do the titles of the most-shared articles all have numbers or other specific characters (like brackets or hyphens) in them?

Is the most-shared content all about a similar topic?

Let's say you run a travel blog and discover that your competitor's article called "How to save money for a trip" is super popular among their audience. You now have an opportunity to create content on a similar topic but make it even better. Maybe "The ultimate guide to traveling on a budget" or even a real story about "How 21-year-old Mike saved $10K for his epic adventure." 

You should also be following all your competitors to learn more about their social media strategy , including which platforms work best for them.

Social media presents an opportunity to let your brand's voice and personality shine. Take Wendy's, for example. The brand publicly roasts its competitors on X (Twitter), and the internet loves it.

Screenshot of a Wendy's tweet

Not every brand can (or should) be quite as blunt and sassy as Wendy's, but showing some personality can pay off.

6. Conduct a final SWOT analysis

A SWOT analysis is a great way to spot opportunities to capitalize on and threats to prepare for before they strike. In short:

Strengths (S) and weaknesses (W) look internally at your company.

Opportunities (O) and threats (T) look externally to the industry and market.

While diving into your competitive market analysis, consider these factors:

Market share percentage: This metric reflects the proportion of sales a company has in the industry compared to its competitors. Tools like Statista or market research reports can offer insights into a brand's dominance or underperformance.

Competitive features: Understand the unique offerings that set a product or service apart from its rivals. Customer surveys and product comparison charts are useful methods to determine standout features.

Company culture: A company's values, work environment, and ethics can be a deciding factor for customers. Monitoring employer review sites like Glassdoor or observing a company's interactions on social media can provide insights.

Customer reviews: Customer reviews provide direct feedback on a product or service's quality and the company's reputation. Platforms like Yelp, Trustpilot, or Google Reviews offer a treasure trove of customer sentiments and concerns.

Geography (if applicable): Location can be pivotal in a company's success, especially for local businesses. Using tools like Google Trends can help identify where a product or brand is most popular geographically.

Let's be clear—this isn't going to shine a spotlight on the exact strategy you should pursue to beat your competitors. What it can do is provide a high-level look at your internal and external environment, making it easier to piece together your competitive strategy.

When promoting your brand, you're thinking about how to communicate your strengths. Conducting a SWOT analysis forces you to also view your brand with scrutiny. You may be working toward being "the best" at everything, but there will inevitably be things that other brands do better.

Download our SWOT analysis template and follow along with the example below to learn as much as possible about your brand and your competitive environment. You can also kick-start the process using ChatGPT.

Example template of a SWOT analysis

Let's say you're the CEO of an automotive company conducting a competitive analysis. After doing a deep dive into your competition and your industry as a whole, organizing your notes and SWOT analyses in folders labeled by competitor, you notice a huge push toward electric vehicles.

In fact, you estimate that your closest competitor (who targets the same market as you) now allocates over half of its advertising budget to its newest electric vehicle release. But you only have one electric vehicle option, and you only allocate 15% of your advertising budget toward it. You reasonably guess that you're in trouble.

Additional research confirms your market is very interested in making the switch to electric. You decide to reallocate your budget toward researching, producing, and promoting electric vehicles. Five years pass, and you realize you would have been left in the dust had you failed to analyze the competition or ignored the warning signs.

Competitive market analysis can prevent wasted resources, inspire new opportunities, and help you stay one step ahead of the competition. Take these six steps to better understand your company's strengths and weaknesses—then identify where you need to improve and how to invest your resources to remain a strong competitor in your industry. 

Sometimes, a company's competitive advantage comes from its seamless internal operations. It can be hard to find out what's going on internally at another company, but you can be sure you streamline your own processes. Here are some tips to get started:

5 things you should automate today

9 ways to leverage automation in the workplace

How to write internal documentation that works

Streamline work across departments with automation

How to build an analysis assistant with ChatGPT

This article was originally published by Diana Ford in May 2021. The most recent update was in September 2023.

Get productivity tips delivered straight to your inbox

We’ll email you 1-3 times per week—and never share your information.

Luke Strauss picture

Luke Strauss

Based in sunny San Diego, Luke is a digital marketer with 3+ years of experience developing and executing content strategy for eCommerce startups and SaaS enterprises alike—Airtable, Zoom, and yes, Zapier—to name a few. When he isn’t diving into a keyword research rabbit hole, you can find him at a music festival, thrifting, or spending time with his friends and family.

  • Small business

Related articles

A hero image representing automation with a lightning bolt

How to choose the best automation software

Hero image for AI in customer service with a globe in the shape of text bubble

AI in customer service: 11 ways to automate support

AI in customer service: 11 ways to automate...

Hero image of a person at a desk writing

How to write a letter of introduction for your freelance business

How to write a letter of introduction for...

Hero image with an icon representing a sales pipeline

How to create a sales plan (and 3 templates that do it for you)

How to create a sales plan (and 3 templates...

Improve your productivity automatically. Use Zapier to get your apps working together.

A Zap with the trigger 'When I get a new lead from Facebook,' and the action 'Notify my team in Slack'

  • Browse All Articles
  • Newsletter Sign-Up

Competition →

research paper on competitive market

  • 29 Feb 2024

Beyond Goals: David Beckham's Playbook for Mobilizing Star Talent

Reach soccer's pinnacle. Become a global brand. Buy a team. Sign Lionel Messi. David Beckham makes success look as easy as his epic free kicks. But leveraging world-class talent takes discipline and deft decision-making, as case studies by Anita Elberse reveal. What could other businesses learn from his ascent?

research paper on competitive market

  • 09 Jan 2024
  • In Practice

Harnessing AI: What Businesses Need to Know in ChatGPT’s Second Year

Companies across industries rushed to adopt ChatGPT last year, seeing its potential to streamline tasks formerly handled by people and vendors at much higher cost. As generative AI enters its next phase in 2024, what can leaders expect? Harvard Business School faculty members highlight four trends to watch.

research paper on competitive market

  • 26 Sep 2023
  • Cold Call Podcast

The PGA Tour and LIV Golf Merger: Competition vs. Cooperation

On June 9, 2022, the first LIV Golf event teed off outside of London. The new tour offered players larger prizes, more flexibility, and ambitions to attract new fans to the sport. Immediately following the official start of that tournament, the PGA Tour announced that all 17 PGA Tour players participating in the LIV Golf event were suspended and ineligible to compete in PGA Tour events. Tensions between the two golf entities continued to rise, as more players “defected” to LIV. Eventually LIV Golf filed an antitrust lawsuit accusing the PGA Tour of anticompetitive practices, and the Department of Justice launched an investigation. Then, in a dramatic turn of events, LIV Golf and the PGA Tour announced that they were merging. Harvard Business School assistant professor Alexander MacKay discusses the competitive, antitrust, and regulatory issues at stake and whether or not the PGA Tour took the right actions in response to LIV Golf’s entry in his case, “LIV Golf.”

research paper on competitive market

  • 19 Sep 2023

How Will the Tech Titans Behind ChatGPT, Bard, and LLaMA Make Money?

It seems like anything is possible with generative AI right now. But how will companies profit from those big ideas? Andy Wu breaks down the potentially painful tradeoffs that tech firms might face as artificial intelligence enters its next phase.

research paper on competitive market

  • 29 Aug 2023

As Social Networks Get More Competitive, Which Ones Will Survive?

In early 2023, TikTok reached close to 1 billion users globally, placing it fourth behind the leading social networks: Facebook, YouTube, and Instagram. Meanwhile, competition in the market for videos had intensified. Can all four networks continue to attract audiences and creators? Felix Oberholzer-Gee discusses competition and imitation among social networks in his case “Hey, Insta & YouTube, Are You Watching TikTok?”

research paper on competitive market

  • 07 Jun 2023

3 Ways to Gain a Competitive Advantage Now: Lessons from Amazon, Chipotle, and Facebook

Remember the Sony Librie? Some people considered it superior to Amazon's Kindle, but it didn't end up the market leader. Rebecca Karp breaks down three methods that companies use to create more value than their rivals—an edge that can make all the difference.

research paper on competitive market

  • 28 Feb 2023

Muhammad Ali: A Case Study in Purpose-Driven Decision Making

Muhammad Ali, born Cassius Marcellus Clay Jr., rose from a poor family in segregated Louisville, Kentucky to international fame, winning three heavyweight boxing titles and becoming a civil rights leader and role model for millions of people around the world. How did he do it? Early in his career, Ali’s creativity and hard work helped him overcome significant obstacles. Rather than letting his fear of flying keep him from competing in the 1960 Olympics, he traveled to Italy wearing a parachute -- and easily won the gold medal in boxing. When he returned to the U.S. as a gold medalist, Ali used his growing fame to bring attention to racism and humanitarian causes he supported, including his then-controversial decision to refuse to fight in the Vietnam War. Professor Robert Simons discusses how Ali made decisions throughout his life and career to leave a lasting impact on the world in his case, “Muhammad Ali: Changing the World.”

research paper on competitive market

  • 21 Jun 2022

Free Isn’t Always Better: How Slack Holds Its Own Against Microsoft Teams

What will it take to win the collaboration app wars: massive scale or a loyal following? A case study by David Yoffie digs into the intense competition between Microsoft Teams and Salesforce's Slack.

research paper on competitive market

  • 28 Apr 2022
  • Research & Ideas

Can You Buy Creativity in the Gig Economy?

It's possible, but creators need more of a stake. A study by Feng Zhu of 10,000 novels in the Chinese e-book market reveals how tying pay to performance can lead to new ideas.

research paper on competitive market

  • 13 Apr 2021
  • Working Paper Summaries

Deregulation, Market Power, and Prices: Evidence from the Electricity Sector

Efforts to deregulate the US electricity sector beginning in the 1990s included market-based prices and restructuring measures to introduce competition. This paper argues that electricity prices increased after deregulation because of the presence of market power.

research paper on competitive market

  • 07 Sep 2020

How to Help Small Businesses Survive COVID's Next Phase

For small businesses that have survived the coronavirus so far, what's next? Karen Mills outlines steps that business owners and government should take immediately. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

research paper on competitive market

  • 03 Sep 2020

Why American Health Care Needs Its Own SEC

The United States needs a health care equivalent of the Securities and Exchange Commission to increase transparency and competition, argues Regina Herzlinger. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 01 Jun 2020
  • What Do You Think?

Will Challenged Amazon Tweak Its Retail Model Post-Pandemic?

James Heskett's readers have little sympathy for Amazon's loss of market share during the pandemic. Has the organization lost its ability to learn? Open for comment; 0 Comments.

research paper on competitive market

  • 21 Apr 2020

7 Successful Battle Strategies to Beat COVID-19

The Agile methodology used to speed complex software development is also helpful for managing decision-making in today's crisis environment, says Euvin Naidoo. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

research paper on competitive market

  • 06 Apr 2020

Where Do Workers Go When the Robots Arrive?

Marco Tabellini and colleagues investigate where workers go after losing their jobs to automation and Chinese imports. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 24 Mar 2020

Free Riding in Loan Approvals: Evidence From SME Lending in Peru

Using data from a large Peruvian bank trying to expand credit access to small and medium enterprises, this study shows that competing lenders use one another’s loan approvals as an input into their own approval process. Such “free riding” has great impact on market outcomes and might warrant policy intervention.

research paper on competitive market

  • 17 Mar 2020

Is There a Winner in Huawei’s Digital Cold War with the US?

Bill Kirby discusses his case study of China-based Huawei’s growth and ultimate confrontation with the United States government, and China's response to the coronavirus. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

research paper on competitive market

  • 09 Mar 2020

Warring Algorithms Could Be Driving Up Consumer Prices

Companies increasingly use software to conduct rapid price changes. Alexander MacKay explains why firms might benefit but consumers should be worried. Open for comment; 0 Comments.

  • 06 Mar 2020

Consumer Protection in an Online World: An Analysis of Occupational Licensing

This paper uses new data collected by a digital platform to study the role of occupational licensing laws on individual choices and market outcomes. Results suggest that more stringent licensing laws restrict competition but do not lead to improvements in customer satisfaction.

  • 25 Feb 2020

Reinventing Retail: The Novel Resurgence of Independent Bookstores

Independent booksellers in the United States have proven resilient in the face of multiple technological and business model shifts in the bookselling industry. By tapping into a larger social movement that promotes the value of shopping local and a desire to cultivate community, successful booksellers are differentiating themselves from online and big box competitors.

.css-s5s6ko{margin-right:42px;color:#F5F4F3;}@media (max-width: 1120px){.css-s5s6ko{margin-right:12px;}} AI that works. Coming June 5th, Asana redefines work management—again. .css-1ixh9fn{display:inline-block;}@media (max-width: 480px){.css-1ixh9fn{display:block;margin-top:12px;}} .css-1uaoevr-heading-6{font-size:14px;line-height:24px;font-weight:500;-webkit-text-decoration:underline;text-decoration:underline;color:#F5F4F3;}.css-1uaoevr-heading-6:hover{color:#F5F4F3;} .css-ora5nu-heading-6{display:-webkit-box;display:-webkit-flex;display:-ms-flexbox;display:flex;-webkit-align-items:center;-webkit-box-align:center;-ms-flex-align:center;align-items:center;-webkit-box-pack:start;-ms-flex-pack:start;-webkit-justify-content:flex-start;justify-content:flex-start;color:#0D0E10;-webkit-transition:all 0.3s;transition:all 0.3s;position:relative;font-size:16px;line-height:28px;padding:0;font-size:14px;line-height:24px;font-weight:500;-webkit-text-decoration:underline;text-decoration:underline;color:#F5F4F3;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:hover{border-bottom:0;color:#CD4848;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:hover path{fill:#CD4848;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:hover div{border-color:#CD4848;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:hover div:before{border-left-color:#CD4848;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:active{border-bottom:0;background-color:#EBE8E8;color:#0D0E10;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:active path{fill:#0D0E10;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:active div{border-color:#0D0E10;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:active div:before{border-left-color:#0D0E10;}.css-ora5nu-heading-6:hover{color:#F5F4F3;} Get early access .css-1k6cidy{width:11px;height:11px;margin-left:8px;}.css-1k6cidy path{fill:currentColor;}

  • Project planning |
  • How to create a competitive analysis (w ...

How to create a competitive analysis (with examples)

How to create a competitive analysis (with examples) article banner image

Competitive analysis involves identifying your direct and indirect competitors using research to reveal their strengths and weaknesses in relation to your own. In this guide, we’ll outline how to do a competitive analysis and explain how you can use this marketing strategy to improve your business.

Whether you’re running a business or playing in a football game, understanding your competition is crucial for success. While you may not be scoring touchdowns in the office, your goal is to score business deals with clients or win customers with your products. The method of preparation for athletes and business owners is similar—once you understand your strengths and weaknesses versus your competitors’, you can level up. 

What is a competitive analysis?

Competitive analysis involves identifying your direct and indirect competitors using research to reveal their strengths and weaknesses in relation to your own. 

[inline illustration] What is a competitive analysis (infographic)

Direct competitors market the same product to the same audience as you, while indirect competitors market the same product to a different audience. After identifying your competitors, you can use the information you gather to see where you stand in the market landscape. 

What to include in a competitive analysis

The purpose of this type of analysis is to get a competitive advantage in the market and improve your business strategy. Without a competitive analysis, it’s difficult to know what others are doing to win clients or customers in your target market. A competitive analysis report may include:

A description of your company’s target market

Details about your product or service versus the competitors’

Current and projected market share, sales, and revenues

Pricing comparison

Marketing and social media strategy analysis

Differences in customer ratings

You’ll compare each detail of your product or service versus the competition to assess strategy efficacy. By comparing success metrics across companies, you can make data-driven decisions.

How to do a competitive analysis

Follow these five steps to create your competitive analysis report and get a broad view of where you fit in the market. This process can help you analyze a handful of competitors at one time and better approach your target customers.

1. Create a competitor overview

In step one, select between five and 10 competitors to compare against your company. The competitors you choose should have similar product or service offerings and a similar business model to you. You should also choose a mix of both direct and indirect competitors so you can see how new markets might affect your company. Choosing both startup and seasoned competitors will further diversify your analysis.

Tip: To find competitors in your industry, use Google or Amazon to search for your product or service. The top results that emerge are likely your competitors. If you’re a startup or you serve a niche market, you may need to dive deeper into the rankings to find your direct competitors.

2. Conduct market research

Once you know the competitors you want to analyze, you’ll begin in-depth market research. This will be a mixture of primary and secondary research. Primary research comes directly from customers or the product itself, while secondary research is information that’s already compiled. Then, keep track of the data you collect in a user research template .

Primary market research may include: 

Purchasing competitors’ products or services

Interviewing customers

Conducting online surveys of customers 

Holding in-person focus groups

Secondary market research may include:

Examining competitors’ websites

Assessing the current economic situation

Identifying technological developments 

Reading company records

Tip: Search engine analysis tools like Ahrefs and SEMrush can help you examine competitors’ websites and obtain crucial SEO information such as the keywords they’re targeting, the number of backlinks they have, and the overall health of their website. 

3. Compare product features

The next step in your analysis involves a comparison of your product to your competitors’ products. This comparison should break down the products feature by feature. While every product has its own unique features, most products will likely include:

Service offered

Age of audience served

Number of features

Style and design

Ease of use

Type and number of warranties

Customer support offered

Product quality

Tip: If your features table gets too long, abbreviate this step by listing the features you believe are of most importance to your analysis. Important features may include cost, product benefits, and ease of use.

4. Compare product marketing

The next step in your analysis will look similar to the one before, except you’ll compare the marketing efforts of your competitors instead of the product features. Unlike the product features matrix you created, you’ll need to go deeper to unveil each company’s marketing plan . 

Areas you’ll want to analyze include:

Social media

Website copy

Press releases

Product copy

As you analyze the above, ask questions to dig deeper into each company’s marketing strategies. The questions you should ask will vary by industry, but may include:

What story are they trying to tell?

What value do they bring to their customers?

What’s their company mission?

What’s their brand voice?

Tip: You can identify your competitors’ target demographic in this step by referencing their customer base, either from their website or from testimonials. This information can help you build customer personas. When you can picture who your competitor actively targets, you can better understand their marketing tactics. 

5. Use a SWOT analysis

Competitive intelligence will make up a significant part of your competitor analysis framework, but once you’ve gathered your information, you can turn the focus back to your company. A SWOT analysis helps you identify your company’s strengths and weaknesses. It also helps turn weaknesses into opportunities and assess threats you face based on your competition.

During a SWOT analysis, ask yourself:

What do we do well?

What could we improve?

Are there market gaps in our services?

What new market trends are on the horizon?

Tip: Your research from the previous steps in the competitive analysis will help you answer these questions and fill in your SWOT analysis. You can visually present your findings in a SWOT matrix, which is a four-box chart divided by category.

6. Identify your place in the market landscape

The last step in your competitive analysis is to understand where you stand in the market landscape. To do this, you’ll create a graph with an X and Y axis. The two axes should represent the most important factors for being competitive in your market. 

For example, the X-axis may represent customer satisfaction, while the Y-axis may represent presence in the market. You’ll then plot each competitor on the graph according to their (x,y) coordinates. You’ll also plot your company on this chart, which will give you an idea of where you stand in relation to your competitors. 

This graph is included for informational purposes and does not represent Asana’s market landscape or any specific industry’s market landscape. 

[inline illustration] Identify your place in the market landscape (infographic)

Tip: In this example, you’ll see three companies that have a greater market presence and greater customer satisfaction than yours, while two companies have a similar market presence but higher customer satisfaction. This data should jumpstart the problem-solving process because you now know which competitors are the biggest threats and you can see where you fall short. 

Competitive analysis example

Imagine you work at a marketing startup that provides SEO for dentists, which is a niche industry and only has a few competitors. You decide to conduct a market analysis for your business. To do so, you would:

Step 1: Use Google to compile a list of your competitors. 

Steps 2, 3, and 4: Use your competitors’ websites, as well as SEO analysis tools like Ahrefs, to deep-dive into the service offerings and marketing strategies of each company. 

Step 5: Focusing back on your own company, you conduct a SWOT analysis to assess your own strategic goals and get a visual of your strengths and weaknesses. 

Step 6: Finally, you create a graph of the market landscape and conclude that there are two companies beating your company in customer satisfaction and market presence. 

After compiling this information into a table like the one below, you consider a unique strategy. To beat out your competitors, you can use localization. Instead of marketing to dentists nationwide like your competitors are doing, you decide to focus your marketing strategy on one region, state, or city. Once you’ve become the known SEO company for dentists in that city, you’ll branch out. 

[inline illustration] Competitive analysis framework (example)

You won’t know what conclusions you can draw from your competitive analysis until you do the work and see the results. Whether you decide on a new pricing strategy, a way to level up your marketing, or a revamp of your product, understanding your competition can provide significant insight.

Drawbacks of competitive analysis

There are some drawbacks to competitive analysis you should consider before moving forward with your report. While these drawbacks are minor, understanding them can make you an even better manager or business owner. 

Don’t forget to take action

You don’t just want to gather the information from your competitive analysis—you also want to take action on that information. The data itself will only show you where you fit into the market landscape. The key to competitive analysis is using it to problem solve and improve your company’s strategic plan .

Be wary of confirmation bias

Confirmation bias means interpreting information based on the beliefs you already hold. This is bad because it can cause you to hold on to false beliefs. To avoid bias, you should rely on all the data available to back up your decisions. In the example above, the business owner may believe they’re the best in the SEO dental market at social media. Because of this belief, when they do market research for social media, they may only collect enough information to confirm their own bias—even if their competitors are statistically better at social media. However, if they were to rely on all the data available, they could eliminate this bias.

Update your analysis regularly

A competitive analysis report represents a snapshot of the market landscape as it currently stands. This report can help you gain enough information to make changes to your company, but you shouldn’t refer to the document again unless you update the information regularly. Market trends are always changing, and although it’s tedious to update your report, doing so will ensure you get accurate insight into your competitors at all times. 

Boost your marketing strategy with competitive analysis

Learning your competitors’ strengths and weaknesses will make you a better marketer. If you don’t know the competition you’re up against, you can’t beat them. Using competitive analysis can boost your marketing strategy and allow you to capture your target audience faster.

Competitive analysis must lead to action, which means following up on your findings with clear business goals and a strong business plan. Once you do your competitive analysis, you can use the templates below to put your plan into action.

Related resources

research paper on competitive market

Smooth product launches are simpler than you think

research paper on competitive market

What is stakeholder analysis and why is it important?

research paper on competitive market

How Asana uses work management to optimize resource planning

research paper on competitive market

Understanding dependencies in project management

After 40 Years, How Representative Are Labor Market Outcomes in the NLSY79?

In 1979, the National Longitudinal Study of Youth 1979 (NLSY79) began following a group of US residents born between 1957 and 1964. It has continued to re-interview these same individuals for more than four decades. Despite this long sampling period, attrition remains modest. This paper shows that after 40 years of data collection, the remaining NLYS79 sample continues to be broadly representative of their national cohorts with regard to key labor market outcomes. For NLSY79 age cohorts, life-cycle profiles of employment, hours worked, and earnings are comparable to those in the Current Population Survey. Moreover, average lifetime earnings over the age range 25 to 55 closely align with the same measure in Social Security Administration data. Our results suggest that the NLSY79 can continue to provide useful data for economists and other social scientists studying life-cycle and lifetime labor market outcomes, including earnings inequality.

We thank Kevin Bloodworth II, Elizabeth Harding, and Siyu Shi for research assistance. The views in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or of the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Richard Rogerson acknowledges financial support in excess of $10,000 over the last three years from the Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and the World Bank.

MARC RIS BibTeΧ

Download Citation Data

More from NBER

In addition to working papers , the NBER disseminates affiliates’ latest findings through a range of free periodicals — the NBER Reporter , the NBER Digest , the Bulletin on Retirement and Disability , the Bulletin on Health , and the Bulletin on Entrepreneurship  — as well as online conference reports , video lectures , and interviews .

15th Annual Feldstein Lecture, Mario Draghi, "The Next Flight of the Bumblebee: The Path to Common Fiscal Policy in the Eurozone cover slide

  • News for Roku

Maintaining Hold: Balancing Roku’s Mixed Results and Competitive Risks in Streaming Market

In a report released today, Jeffrey Wlodarczak from Pivotal Research reiterated a Hold rating on Roku ( ROKU – Research Report ), with a price target of $75.00 .

Jeffrey Wlodarczak has given his Hold rating due to a combination of factors impacting Roku’s business. His analysis acknowledges the mixed results in the company’s first-quarter earnings and second-quarter guidance, where Roku experienced worse-than-expected net new streaming household additions but performed better in gross profit and free cash flow. Despite tough comparables due to previous accounting adjustments and an uneven advertising recovery, Roku’s impressive cost control management is a highlight that has positively influenced Wlodarczak’s EBITDA and free cash flow estimates for 2024. However, he has slightly lowered his expectations for net new streaming households and platform revenue. Furthermore, Wlodarczak notes Roku’s strong standing in the streaming market, given its substantial U.S. household penetration and high-quality streaming aggregation product. Yet the company faces significant competitive risks from large players with deep pockets who are recognizing the value in streaming aggregation and could subsidize their streaming ventures. The proliferation of advertising inventory and potential market consolidation also pose threats to Roku’s advertising-based revenue model. Despite these challenges, Roku’s market position and product strength are considered formidable, leading Wlodarczak to maintain his year-end target price and reiterate the Hold rating.

Based on the recent corporate insider activity of 80 insiders, corporate insider sentiment is positive on the stock. This means that over the past quarter there has been an increase of insiders buying their shares of ROKU in relation to earlier this year.

TipRanks tracks over 100,000 company insiders, identifying the select few who excel in timing their transactions. By upgrading to TipRanks Premium, you will gain access to this exclusive data and discover crucial insights to guide your investment decisions. Begin your TipRanks Premium journey today.

Roku (ROKU) Company Description:

Founded in 2002 and based in California, Roku, Inc. is a television streaming platform. It operates through two business segments: Player and Platform. The Player segment consists of net sales of streaming media players and accessories through retailers and distributors, as well as directly to customers through the company’s website. Its Roku platform allows users to personalize their content selection with cable television replacement offerings and other streaming services that suit their budget and needs.

Read More on ROKU:

  • Options Volatility and Implied Earnings Moves Today, April 25, 2024
  • Investors Rush for Exits from Cathie Wood’s ARK Funds
  • Options Volatility and Implied Earnings Moves This Week, April 22 – April 26, 2024
  • Unusually active option classes on open April 19th
  • Roku price target lowered to $80 from $120 at Wedbush

Roku News MORE

Related stocks.

research paper on competitive market

  • Study Guides
  • Homework Questions

MKT-630 1-2 Short Paper Roles and Benefits of Marketing Research

Skip to Content

The U.S. labor market can affect ‘people who are not even here,’ research finds

  • Share via Twitter
  • Share via Facebook
  • Share via LinkedIn
  • Share via E-mail

A recently published paper co-authored by Brian Cadena finds deep connections between the U.S. and Mexican economies

That the job market in Phoenix can affect a child’s education in Mexico may strain credulity, but it’s nevertheless true, according to a recent  paper co-authored by Brian Cadena , a University of Colorado Boulder associate professor of economics.  

People from specific regions in Mexico tend to migrate to specific regions in the United States, and when U.S. work dries up in some areas, those migrants tend to return to Mexico, Cadena and his co-authors, María Esther Caballero of American University and Brian K. Kovak of Carnegie Mellon, found.

Their paper, published in the Journal of International Economics in November, explores the U.S. labor market’s influence on the lives of people in Mexico by comparing how neighboring Mexican counties, or “municipios,” fared during the Great Recession.

Brian Cadena

Brian Cadena, a CU Boulder associate professor of economics, and his research colleagues explore the U.S. labor market’s influence on the lives of people in Mexico by comparing how neighboring Mexican counties fared during the Great Recession.

To perform their analysis, Cadena, Caballero and Kovak drew upon data from the Matrícula Consular de Alta Seguridad (MCAS), a governmental organization that issues identity cards to Mexican migrants.

Unlike either the U.S. or Mexican census, MCAS provides in-depth, granular information on migrant workers, specifying the municipios they leave and where in the United States they settle.

MCAS is a treasure trove, says Cadena. But it wasn’t long ago that researchers didn’t know how to use it. Cadena, Caballero and Kovak changed that with another paper they published in 2018, which validated the MCAS data and thereby opened up a whole range of potential research.

“This identity-card data really allowed us to drill down and make tight comparisons between municipios,” says Cadena.  

The strength of networks

A key finding that emerged from the MCAS data is that people from the same municipio often move to the same cities and states in the United States. “People follow their networks,” says Cadena. And these networks are so strong that migrants from nearby municipios often end up hundreds of miles apart in the States.

Migrants from the municipio of Dolores Hidalgo, for example, tend to move to Texas, while those from nearby Jaral del Progreso generally relocate to Chicago, California and the Southwest. Same region in Mexico, different time zones in the United States.

The close proximity of the municipios is important for the kind of research Cadena, Caballero and Kovak are doing, Cadena explains, because it cuts down on confounding variables. Neighboring municipios experience the same weather, suffer the same droughts, follow the same or similar laws, etc., which means differences in their economic outcomes are likely due to something they don’t share—the job market in the cities and states where their migrants moved.

To unearth these differences, Cadena, Caballero and Kovak measured the job-market losses in the U.S. regions linked to each municipio and then compared the economic outcomes in the municipios connected to harder-hit regions to those connected to softer-hit regions.

As it happens, labor demand in Texas survived the Great Recession relatively unscathed, so the municipios of the migrants who ventured there remained stable. The American Southwest, however, suffered some major blows, and so the municipios connected to that region exhibited several changes.

(Un)expected observations

Some of those changes were unsurprising, says Cadena.

United States and Mexico flags

“One of the things we’re finding is how connected these two economies are," says CU Boulder researcher Brian Cadena of the United States and Mexico. On the one hand, the stark differences in what someone can earn and what the labor market looks like in one country as opposed to the other suggests that we have made the separation between those countries real and meaningful. On the other hand, we are certainly not islands.”

“When work dried up, more immigrants returned to Mexico, and fewer new immigrants came from that source community.” This then led to a fall in remittances, or money transfers from migrant workers to their families back in Mexico.  

Yet Cadena, Caballero and Kovak also observed some changes they didn’t expect. One was that more women joined the Mexican workforce.

“This is called the added worker effect,” says Cadena. “When the primary earner of a household”—in this case, the migrant laborer—“loses their job, it’s a common reaction by the household to say, ‘Let’s send someone else to work.’”

Another unexpected change was a drop in school retention. “We found some suggestive evidence that a loss of jobs in the United States reduced investment in schooling in Mexico. We saw more schooling dropout, especially at transition ages, when kids move from one level of schooling to the next,” says Cadena.

Blurred lines and better choices

What do these findings suggest about the perceived separation between these two countries and their economies?

It makes that separation “a little fuzzier,” says Cadena.

“One of the things we’re finding is how connected these two economies are. On the one hand, the stark differences in what someone can earn and what the labor market looks like in one country as opposed to the other suggests that we have made the separation between those countries real and meaningful. On the other hand, we are certainly not islands.”

Realizing this, Cadena believes, could inform policymaking, specifically regarding immigration.

“When we’re thinking about immigration policy—when we’re thinking about all these things that affect the low-wage labor market—we are making policy that has a real and noticeable effect on the lives of people who are not even here,” he says.

“I’m not a politician, but I think that a more holistic sense of all the impacts of the choices we make as a country could help us make better choices.”

Did you enjoy this article?  Subcribe to our newsletter.  Passionate about economics?  Show your support.

Related Articles

Girl, baby, woman and young man in Dhaka, Bangladesh

Early childhood health interventions have ‘big, multi-generation impacts,’ research finds

Crime scene tape and police cars with lights on

Understanding crime through both victims and offenders

Woman carrying baby walking into corrugated metal home

Legal rights and legal reality diverge for single women in Nepal

  • Division of Social Sciences

Apple loses top spot in China market with shipments down 6.6% in Q1, data shows

  • Medium Text

People look at the new iPhone 15 Pro as Apple's new iPhone 15 officially goes on sale across China at an Apple store in Shanghai

Sign up here.

Reporting by Mrinmay Dey in Bengaluru; Editing by Varun H K

Our Standards: The Thomson Reuters Trust Principles. New Tab , opens new tab

Illustration shows the US flag and TikTok logos

Technology Chevron

Illustration shows words

Beijing city to subsidise domestic AI chips, targets self-reliance by 2027

Beijing city authorities have announced subsidies for firms that purchase domestically produced artificial intelligence (AI) chips, as China seeks to develop its semiconductor industry and reduce reliance on foreign technology.

The Roku company logo is displayed on a building in Austin, Texas

IMAGES

  1. FREE 42+ Research Paper Examples in PDF

    research paper on competitive market

  2. Market Research Examples

    research paper on competitive market

  3. How a Market Research Benefits Your Business

    research paper on competitive market

  4. 🌈 Example of marketing research paper. 38 Marketing Plan Examples

    research paper on competitive market

  5. Solved 1. Characteristics of competitive markets The

    research paper on competitive market

  6. Research paper on marketing pdf

    research paper on competitive market

VIDEO

  1. Percentage Math Past Papers Solved Questions For PPSC, FPSC, SPSC, KPPSC, BPSC and other Competitive

  2. CTET SOCIAL SCIENCE PYQ Paper Analysis by Sachin choudhary live 8pm

  3. Game-changer for understanding the #marketplace industry and your competitors #ecommerce #report

  4. Perfect Competition (Part 1): An Introduction

  5. February 2024 Complete Current Affairs according to PPSC, FPSC and Other one Paper competitive Exams

  6. Urdu Grammar lecture 3

COMMENTS

  1. Competitive pricing on online markets: a literature review

    Especially for research in the economics stream, many papers assume a perfectly competitive market. Pricing research with perfectly competitive markets (e.g., van Mieghem and Dada 1999 or Yang and Xia 2013) is likely to be of very limited value to online retailers.

  2. Market Research and Insight: Past, Present and Future

    One hundred years have passed since the founding of the first independent market research firm in the UK in 1921. This important milestone inspired this special issue of the International Journal of Market Research that explores the role and importance of market research through a historical lens. A historical approach enables recognising and (re)framing both academic and practitioner ...

  3. Business Strategies and Competitive Advantage: The Role ...

    Competitive advantage is at the heart of a company's performance in a competitive market ... This includes company policies, market interactions, research, technology, and resource capabilities [34]. ... The number of data tested was 150, and the value of the t table (α = 5%) was 1975. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.

  4. A Review of Global Competitiveness Research: Past Advances and Future

    Kohli Ajay, and Jaworski Bernard J. (1990), "Market Orientation: The Construct, Research Propositions, and Managerial Implications," Journal of Marketing, 54(2), 1-18. Crossref. ... "What in the World Is Competitive Advantage?" working paper no. 2003-105, Anderson School of Management, University of California, Los Angeles.

  5. (PDF) Pricing and price competition in consumer markets

    Pricing and price competition in consumer markets 127. assume that market shares are independent of the market price, so that the price leader's. profits (excluding fixed costs) will be. π ...

  6. A step-by-step guide to competitive market analysis

    Market share percentage: This metric reflects the proportion of sales a company has in the industry compared to its competitors. Tools like Statista or market research reports can offer insights into a brand's dominance or underperformance. Competitive features: Understand the unique offerings that set a product or service apart from its rivals ...

  7. Competitive Strategy: Articles, Research, & Case Studies on Competitive

    New research on competitive strategy from Harvard Business School faculty on issues including Michael E. Porter's pioneering work on the "five forces," how nations compete, and the unique challenges of competing in a digital world. ... but it didn't end up the market leader. Rebecca Karp breaks down three methods that companies use to create ...

  8. Competition: Articles, Research, & Case Studies on Competition- HBS

    This paper uses new data collected by a digital platform to study the role of occupational licensing laws on individual choices and market outcomes. Results suggest that more stringent licensing laws restrict competition but do not lead to improvements in customer satisfaction. 25 Feb 2020. Working Paper Summaries.

  9. Competitive Dynamics Between Multinational Companies and Local Rivals

    Building on these perceptions, research into competitive dynamics ... The final period is used to define the market leader. The competitive dynamics and co-evolution of Delta and Emirates during the previous three periods show that Emirates possesses many competitive advantages to become the market leader, because it possesses all the required ...

  10. Conceptualizing competition and rivalry in a networking business market

    The concept of competition shifts in meaning depending on the context. In the business-to-business literature the meaning extends on a scale from rivalry ( Baum and Korn, 1996, Luo, 2007, Porac et al., 1995) to coopetition ( Bengtsson and Kock, 2014, Rusko, 2011 ). However, these concepts were developed within the context of inter-firm ...

  11. (PDF) Competitive Marketing Strategy

    competitive marketing plans for two important reasons. First, the value-based market opportunities typically require changes to the product or. service itself, new methods for marketing ...

  12. (PDF) Global Marketing: Emerging Market Economies' Challenges

    The paper's purpose has been to conduct a rigorous literature review and analyze emerging market economies' competitive marketing environment.

  13. JOItmC

    This study aims to examine the effect of business strategies to improve the competitive advantages of small and medium enterprises (SMEs). Further, our study considers the importance of performance and innovation as mediating variables in the relationship between business strategies and competitive advantage. The sample of the study consists of 150 SMEs in the construction and real estate ...

  14. Conduct a Competitive Analysis (With Examples) [2024] • Asana

    You decide to conduct a market analysis for your business. To do so, you would: Step 1: Use Google to compile a list of your competitors. Steps 2, 3, and 4: Use your competitors' websites, as well as SEO analysis tools like Ahrefs, to deep-dive into the service offerings and marketing strategies of each company.

  15. Toward a Theory of Competitive Market Signaling: A Research Agenda

    This paper develops a set of propositions based on research in economics, social psychology, and marketing on the risklreward trade-off in signaling, the receiver's signal interpretation, and the receiver's reaction alternatives. The overall objective is to develop a research agenda toward a theory of competitive market signaling.

  16. After 40 Years, How Representative Are Labor Market Outcomes in the

    This paper shows that after 40 years of data collection, the remaining NLYS79 sample continues to be broadly representative of their national cohorts with regard to key labor market outcomes. For NLSY79 age cohorts, life-cycle profiles of employment, hours worked, and earnings are comparable to those in the Current Population Survey.

  17. Market Structure: The Analysis of Markets and Competition

    The Analysis of Markets and Competition. The critical market-level influence on firm performance is the form and intensity of rivalry. between the existing firms in a market. The economist's ...

  18. Maintaining Hold: Balancing Roku's Mixed Results and Competitive Risks

    Despite these challenges, Roku's market position and product strength are considered formidable, leading Wlodarczak to maintain his year-end target price and reiterate the Hold rating.

  19. MKT-630 1-2 Short Paper Roles and Benefits of Marketing Research

    Marketing document from Southern New Hampshire University, 4 pages, MKT-630 1-2 Short Paper: Roles and Benefits of Marketing Research Ashley Truskowski 09/23/2023 Market research is important for gaining and maintaining a competitive advantage in business. Considering consumer behavior, demand, market saturation, pricing

  20. Competition and monopoly in the U.S. economy: What do the industrial

    Industrial concentration and monopolization in the U.S. economy has attracted significant attention in the last few years. A recent literature emphasizes increasing concentration ratios and market power over the last two decades, and argues that this increase is a significant factor behind a number of major macroeconomic trends, including rising corporate profits, slowing investment, declining ...

  21. The U.S. labor market can affect 'people who are not even here

    That the job market in Phoenix can affect a child's education in Mexico may strain credulity, but it's nevertheless true, according to a recent paper co-authored by Brian Cadena, a University of Colorado Boulder associate professor of economics. People from specific regions in Mexico tend to migrate to specific regions in the United States, and when U.S. work dries up in some areas, those ...

  22. Why AMD, Applied Materials, and Lam Research Stocks All Tumbled Today

    And you can see why that might worry investors. According to S&P Global Market Intelligence data, AMD got 22% of its revenue from China in 2022 -- but by 2023, that number had dwindled to only 15% ...

  23. Research Day 2024 Recap: Winners and Videos

    The Bloustein School's 3rd Annual Research Day took place in person at the Gov. James J. Florio Special Events Forum on Friday, April 12th. The event was an opportunity for Bloustein students, faculty, and staff to showcase their research, receive feedback, and build networks around common research interests.

  24. (PDF) Report

    This paper analyzes the effects of market orientation and innovation on competitive advantage and business performance. The method of collecting data is a designed questionnaire. The sample size ...

  25. Huawei sales are soaring in China as Apple sinks

    Counterpoint's data comes just days after another market research firm IDC said Apple's global smartphone sales had tumbled 10% in the first quarter, mainly because of loss of momentum in China.

  26. Apple loses top spot in China market with shipments down 6.6% in Q1

    Honor and Huawei were tied for the top spot, with Honor's market share rising to 17.1% and Huawei's share climbing to 17%, IDC said, while the iPhone maker's market share fell to 15.6%.

  27. (PDF) Perfect Competition and the Creativity of the Market

    An Economy with Two-Sided Perfect Competition. Full Appropriation Leads to Efficient Price-Making and Market-Making. Imperfect Competition Leads to Inappropriable Benefits, Hence to Inefficient ...