- Search Search Please fill out this field.
What Was the Stock Market Crash of 1929?
- Understanding the Crash
Public Utilities In 1929
Bank failures and the great depression, legislation after 1929.
- Stock Market Crash of 1929 FAQs
The Bottom Line
- Stock Markets
Stock Market Crash of 1929: Definition, Causes, Effects
Andy Smith is a Certified Financial Planner (CFP®), licensed realtor and educator with over 35 years of diverse financial management experience. He is an expert on personal finance, corporate finance and real estate and has assisted thousands of clients in meeting their financial goals over his career.
- Guide to Stock Market Crashes
- October: The Month of Market Crashes?
- How Do Investors Lose Money When the Stock Market Crashes?
- Timeline of U.S. Stock Market Crashes
- October Effect
- Financial Crisis
- Circuit Breaker
- Plunge Protection Team
- Dutch Tulip Bulb Market Bubble
- Black Friday
- Bank Panic of 1907
- Stock Market Crash of 1929 CURRENT ARTICLE
- What Caused the Stock Market Crash of 1929
- Black Tuesday
- Black Thursday
- Stock Market Crash of 1987
- Black Monday
- What Caused Black Monday: The Stock Market Crash of 1987
- The 2007-2008 Financial Crisis in Review
- The Fall of the Market in the Fall of 2008
- Components of the 2008 Bubble
- Financial Regulations: Glass-Steagall to Dodd-Frank
- Consequences of the Glass-Steagall Act Repeal
- Lessons from the 2008 Financial Crisis
- Major Players in the 2008 Financial Crisis: Where Are They Now?
- Too Big to Fail Banks: Where Are They Now?
The stock market crash of 1929 began on "Black Monday, Oct. 28, 1929, when the Dow Jones Industrial Average (DJIA) plunged nearly 13% in heavy trading. While panic selling occurred in the first week, the greatest decline occurred in the following two years as the Great Depression emerged. The DJIA hit its lowest point on July 8, 1932, 89% below its September 1929 peak, defining the most significant bear market in Wall Street’s history. The market would not return to its 1929 high until 1954.
Key Takeaways
- The stock market crash of 1929 began on "Black Monday," Oct. 28, 1929, when panicked investors sent the DJIA plunging nearly 13% in heavy trading.
- The 1929 crash followed a decade of economic growth and a bull market .
- The stock market crash was followed by the Great Depression , which lasted until World War II.
- Congress passed federal regulations to stabilize the markets, such as the Glass Steagall Act of 1933 .
Understanding the Stock Market Crash of 1929
The stock market crash of 1929 followed a bull market marked by a five-year rise of the DJIA. Industrial companies traded at price-to-earnings ratios (P/E ratios) over 15, and valuations did not appear unreasonable after a decade of record productivity growth in manufacturing.
Overproduction in many industries caused an oversupply of steel, iron, and durable goods. When it became clear that demand was low and there were not enough buyers for goods, manufacturers dumped their products at a loss, and share prices plummeted.
The Federal Reserve attempted to curtail investor speculation, raising the rediscount rate to 6% from 5% in August 1929, a move that some experts say stalled economic growth and reduced stock market liquidity , making the markets more vulnerable to rapid price drops.
By 1929, many electric companies were consolidated into holding companies controlling about two-thirds of the American industry. The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) reported in 1928 that the unfair practices these holding companies conducted, including bilking subsidiaries through service contracts and fraudulent accounting involving depreciation and inflated property values, were a menace to the investor. In October 1929, as new legislation was proposed to regulate the public utilities industry, the resulting sell-off cascaded through the system as investors who had bought stocks on margin became forced sellers.
The Federal Reserve hesitated to address the initial crash and prevent the wave of bank failures that paralyzed the financial system. As Treasury Secretary Andrew Mellon told President Herbert Hoover: "Liquidate labor, liquidate stocks, liquidate the farmers, liquidate real estate…It’ll purge the rottenness out of the system."
The crash was exacerbated by the collapse of foreign bonds . Because the demand for American exports had been supported by funds lent to overseas borrowers, this vendor-financed demand for American goods disappeared.
At the end of the crash, the market lost $30 billion in value or approximately $528 billion in today's money.
The stock market crash signaled the Great Depression , where 15 million Americans lost jobs, and half of the country's banks failed by 1933. Production and demand fell, sparking bread lines and homelessness across the nation. Farmers were forced to let crops rot, and many starved. Many farmers migrated to the cities looking for jobs as droughts caused high winds and dust in the south, known as the Dust Bowl.
The Great Depression ushered in an era of isolationism, protectionism, and nationalism. The infamous Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act in 1930 started a spiral of beggar-thy-neighbor economic policies. The lack of government oversight is regarded as a cause of the 1929 crash, with policies based on laissez-faire economic theories. In response, Congress passed federal regulations aimed at stabilizing the markets.
- The Glass Steagall-Act of 1933 forced commercial banks to refrain from investment banking activities to protect depositors from potential losses caused by bank speculation. The Act also created the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation .
- The Securities Exchange Act of 1934 was created to govern securities transactions on the secondary market to ensure greater financial transparency and less fraud or manipulation.
- The Public Utility Holding Companies Act of 1935 effectively dismantled the nation's biggest electric companies to limit the damage of a single company failure.
What Was Black Monday?
The great Wall Street crash of 1929 began on Oct. 28, 1929, known as Black Monday, but witnessed a further decline, such as on Oct. 29, 1929, known as Black Tuesday.
Did the Stock Market Crash in 1929 Cause a Shift in Culture During the 1930s?
The stock market crash of 1929 had a devastating effect on the culture of the 1930s. As investors, businesses, and farms lost money, they started to shutter and lay off workers. Banks closed as well. The Great Depression began in the 1930s, leading to soup kitchens, bread lines, and homelessness. The culture in the 30s shifted dramatically from that in the 20s. The 20s, known as the roaring 20s, saw a period of economic growth and consumerism after the war, while the 1930s witnessed poverty and economic decline.
What Factors Led to the Stock Market Crash of 1929?
Historians contribute a variety of factors that led to the stock market crash of 1929, such as tremendous speculation during the roaring twenties; a significant expansion of debt; a decline in production which led to a rise in unemployment, which led to a decline in spending; low wages; an agricultural sector in distress, and banks that had large loans that could not be liquidated.
Factors that led to the stock market crash of 1929 included significant market speculation, expansion of debt, a decline in production and spending, and a distressed agricultural sector. On Monday, Oct. 28, 1929, panicked investor selling led to a nearly 13% loss in the Dow Jones Industrial Average. The stock market crash was followed by the Great Depression, which lasted until World War II.
Britannica. " Great Depression ."
Federal Reserve History. " Stock Market Crash of 1929 ."
Federal Reserve History. " Banking Act of 1933 (Glass-Steagall) ."
EH.net. " The 1929 Stock Market Crash ."
International Banker. " History of Financial Crises, The Stock Market Crash of 1929 ."
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. " The Discount Rate Controversy Between the Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York ," Page 1.
JSTOR. " Public Utilities Legislation of 1929 ."
Federal Trade Commission. " ANNUAL REPORT OF THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION FOR THE FISCAL YEAR ENDED JUNE 30 1935 ," Page 26-29.
EconLib. " Krugman Gets Hoover Wrong ."
University of Hawaii System. " The Stock Market Crash of 1929 ."
History.com. " Great Depression History ."
Britannica. " Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act ."
GovInfo. " Securities Exchange Act of 1934 ."
U.S. Energy Information Administration. " Public Utility Holding Company Act of 1935: 1935-1992 ."
History.com. " Stock Market Crash of 1929 ."
- Terms of Service
- Editorial Policy
- Privacy Policy
- Your Privacy Choices
Stock Market Crash of 1929
October 1929.
The Roaring Twenties roared loudest and longest on the New York Stock Exchange. Share prices rose to unprecedented heights. The Dow Jones Industrial Average increased six-fold from sixty-three in August 1921 to 381 in September 1929. After prices peaked, economist Irving Fisher proclaimed, “stock prices have reached ‘what looks like a permanently high plateau.’” 1
The epic boom ended in a cataclysmic bust. On Black Monday, October 28, 1929, the Dow declined nearly 13 percent. On the following day, Black Tuesday, the market dropped nearly 12 percent. By mid-November, the Dow had lost almost half of its value. The slide continued through the summer of 1932, when the Dow closed at 41.22, its lowest value of the twentieth century, 89 percent below its peak. The Dow did not return to its pre-crash heights until November 1954.
The financial boom occurred during an era of optimism. Families prospered. Automobiles, telephones, and other new technologies proliferated. Ordinary men and women invested growing sums in stocks and bonds. A new industry of brokerage houses, investment trusts, and margin accounts enabled ordinary people to purchase corporate equities with borrowed funds. Purchasers put down a fraction of the price, typically 10 percent, and borrowed the rest. The stocks that they bought served as collateral for the loan. Borrowed money poured into equity markets, and stock prices soared.
Skeptics existed, however. Among them was the Federal Reserve. The governors of many Federal Reserve Banks and a majority of the Federal Reserve Board believed stock-market speculation diverted resources from productive uses, like commerce and industry. The Board asserted that the “Federal Reserve Act does not … contemplate the use of the resources of the Federal Reserve Banks for the creation or extension of speculative credit” (Chandler 1971, 56). 2
The Board’s opinion stemmed from the text of the act. Section 13 authorized reserve banks to accept as collateral for discount loans assets that financed agricultural, commercial, and industrial activity but prohibited them from accepting as collateral “notes, drafts, or bills covering merely investments or issued or drawn for the purpose of carrying or trading in stocks, bonds or other investment securities, except bonds and notes of the Government of the United States” (Federal Reserve Act 1913).
Section 14 of the act extended those powers and prohibitions to purchases in the open market. 3
These provisions reflected the theory of real bills, which had many adherents among the authors of the Federal Reserve Act in 1913 and leaders of the Federal Reserve System in 1929. This theory indicated that the central bank should issue money when production and commerce expanded, and contract the supply of currency and credit when economic activity contracted.
The Federal Reserve decided to act. The question was how. The Federal Reserve Board and the leaders of the reserve banks debated this question. To rein in the tide of call loans, which fueled the financial euphoria, the Board favored a policy of direct action. The Board asked reserve banks to deny requests for credit from member banks that loaned funds to stock speculators. 4 The Board also warned the public of the dangers of speculation.
The governor of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, George Harrison, favored a different approach. He wanted to raise the discount lending rate. This action would directly increase the rate that banks paid to borrow funds from the Federal Reserve and indirectly raise rates paid by all borrowers, including firms and consumers. In 1929, New York repeatedly requested to raise its discount rate; the Board denied several of the requests. In August the Board finally acquiesced to New York’s plan of action, and New York’s discount rate reached 6 percent. 5
The Federal Reserve’s rate increase had unintended consequences. Because of the international gold standard, the Fed’s actions forced foreign central banks to raise their own interest rates. Tight-money policies tipped economies around the world into recession. International commerce contracted, and the international economy slowed (Eichengreen 1992; Friedman and Schwartz 1963; Temin 1993).
The financial boom, however, continued. The Federal Reserve watched anxiously. Commercial banks continued to loan money to speculators, and other lenders invested increasing sums in loans to brokers. In September 1929, stock prices gyrated, with sudden declines and rapid recoveries. Some financial leaders continued to encourage investors to purchase equities, including Charles E. Mitchell, the president of the National City Bank (now Citibank) and a director of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 6 In October, Mitchell and a coalition of bankers attempted to restore confidence by publicly purchasing blocks of shares at high prices. The effort failed. Investors began selling madly. Share prices plummeted.
Funds that fled the stock market flowed into New York City’s commercial banks. These banks also assumed millions of dollars in stock-market loans. The sudden surges strained banks. As deposits increased, banks’ reserve requirements rose; but banks’ reserves fell as depositors withdrew cash, banks purchased loans, and checks (the principal method of depositing funds) cleared slowly. The counterpoised flows left many banks temporarily short of reserves.
To relieve the strain, the New York Fed sprang into action. It purchased government securities on the open market, expedited lending through its discount window, and lowered the discount rate. It assured commercial banks that it would supply the reserves they needed. These actions increased total reserves in the banking system, relaxed the reserve constraint faced by banks in New York City, and enabled financial institutions to remain open for business and satisfy their customers’ demands during the crisis. The actions also kept short term interest rates from rising to disruptive levels, which frequently occurred during financial crises.
At the time, the New York Fed’s actions were controversial. The Board and several reserve banks complained that New York exceeded its authority. In hindsight, however, these actions helped to contain the crisis in the short run. The stock market collapsed, but commercial banks near the center of the storm remained in operation (Friedman and Schwartz 1963).
While New York’s actions protected commercial banks, the stock-market crash still harmed commerce and manufacturing. The crash frightened investors and consumers. Men and women lost their life savings, feared for their jobs, and worried whether they could pay their bills. Fear and uncertainty reduced purchases of big ticket items, like automobiles, that people bought with credit. Firms – like Ford Motors – saw demand decline, so they slowed production and furloughed workers. Unemployment rose, and the contraction that had begun in the summer of 1929 deepened (Romer 1990; Calomiris 1993). 7
While the crash of 1929 curtailed economic activity, its impact faded within a few months, and by the fall of 1930 economic recovery appeared imminent. Then, problems in another portion of the financial system turned what may have been a short, sharp recession into our nation’s longest, deepest depression.
From the stock market crash of 1929, economists – including the leaders of the Federal Reserve – learned at least two lessons. 8
First, central banks – like the Federal Reserve – should be careful when acting in response to equity markets. Detecting and deflating financial bubbles is difficult. Using monetary policy to restrain investors’ exuberance may have broad, unintended, and undesirable consequences. 9
Second, when stock market crashes occur, their damage can be contained by following the playbook developed by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in the fall of 1929.
Economists and historians debated these issues during the decades following the Great Depression. Consensus coalesced around the time of the publication of Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz’s A Monetary History of the United States in 1963. Their conclusions concerning these events are cited by many economists, including members of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors such as Ben Bernanke, Donald Kohn and Frederic Mishkin.
In reaction to the financial crisis of 2008 scholars may be rethinking these conclusions. Economists have been questioning whether central banks can and should prevent asset market bubbles and how concerns about financial stability should influence monetary policy. These widespread discussions hearken back to the debates on this issue among the leaders of the Federal Reserve during the 1920s.
- 1 Irving Fisher’s quote appeared in the New York Times on October 16, 1929, p. 8. Fisher made the comment in a speech at the monthly dinner of the Purchasing Agents Association at the Builders Exchange Club, 2 Park Avenue. At the time, Fisher was one of the nation’s most well-known and widely quoted economists. His comments came in response to a prediction on September 5 at the Annual National Business Conference by rival financial prognosticator, Roger Babson, that “sooner or later a crash is coming, and it may be terrific.” Babson’s comment was followed by a sharp decline in stock-market prices known as the Babson break. Fisher reiterated his faith in the stock market in a speech before the District of Columbia Bankers Association on October 23.
- 2 The Board made these statements in its famous letter from February 2, 1929. For the text of the letter and discussion of its implications see Chandler 1971, pp. 56-58.
- 3 In addition to assets that could serve as collateral for discount loans, Section 14 authorized open market purchases of (a) gold coins, bullion, and certificates, and (b) securities issued and guaranteed by “any State, county, district, political subdivision, or municipality in the continental United States” (Federal Reserve Act 1913).
- 4 These requests appear in the Board’s letter of February 2, 1929. See Chandler 1971, pp. 56-58.
- 5 In this brief essay, we focus on the clash of opinions between the leaders of the Federal Reserve Board in Washington, DC, and leaders of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Several of the authors that we cite also highlight this line of debate. We should note that leaders throughout the Federal Reserve System vigorously debated this issue, and differences of opinion existed between the Board and leaders of many banks and also within those leadership groups. At times, for example, members of the Federal Reserve Board disagreed with each other about the appropriate course of action; policy proposals frequently passed only with split votes and after vigorous discussion and dissent. Differences of opinion also existed among the board of directors of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and between leaders in New York, Washington, and other cities. An overview of the system-wide debate appears in Chandler 1971, pp. 54-70.
- 6 Galbraith characterizes Mitchell as one of the two prominent “prophets” of the stock market boom, the other being Irving Fisher.
- 7 The account that we present is, in our opinion, the academic consensus, although on this issue we note that Meltzer (2003, 252-257) and other scholars suggest that the crash was a symptom, not a contributing force, to the contraction in 1929.
- 8 Friedman and Schwartz (1963) outline these lessons in their coverage of the stock market crash. Meltzer (2003) reaches similar conclusions in his history of the Federal Reserve. Chairmen of the Federal Reserve, including Bernanke and Greenspan, echoed these sentiments in their writings and speeches in recent decades.
- 9 Irrational exuberance is, of course, a phrase popularized by Alan Greenspan and typically cited to this speech.
Bibliography
Bernanke, Ben, “ Asset Price ‘Bubbles’ and Monetary Policy .” Remarks before the New York Chapter of the National Association for Business Economics, New York, NY, October 15, 2002.
Calomiris, Charles W. “Financial Factors in the Great Depression.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 7, no. 2 (Spring 1993): 61-85.
Chandler, Lester V. American Monetary Policy, 1928-1941 . New York: Harper and Row, 1971.
Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919 –1929 . Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1992.
Federal Reserve Act, 1913. Pub. L. 63-43, ch. 6, 38 Stat. 251 (1913).
Friedman, Milton and Anna Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States . Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.
Galbraith, John Kenneth. The Great Crash of 1929 . New York: Houghton Mifflin, 1954.
Greenspan, Alan, “ The Challenge of Central Banking in a Democratic Society ,” Remarks at the Annual Dinner and Francis Boyer Lecture of The American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, DC, December 5, 1996.
Klein, Maury. “The Stock Market Crash of 1929: A Review Article.” Business History Review 75, no. 2 (Summer 2001): 325-351.
Kohn, Donald, “ Monetary policy and asset prices ,” Speech at “Monetary Policy: A Journey from Theory to Practice,” a European Central Bank Colloquium held in honor of Otmar Issing, Frankfurt, Germany, March 16, 2006.
Meltzer, Allan. A History of the Federal Reserve, Volume 1, 1913-1951 . Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2003.
Mishkin, Frederic, “ How Should We Respond to Asset Price Bubbles? ” Comments at the Wharton Financial Institutions Center and Oliver Wyman Institute's Annual Financial Risk Roundtable, Philadelphia, PA, May 15, 2008.
Romer, Christina. “The Great Crash and the Onset of the Great Depression.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 105, no. 3 (August 1990): 597-624.
Temin, Peter. “Transmission of the Great Depression.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 7, no. 2 (Spring 1993): 87-102.
Written as of November 22, 2013. See disclaimer .
Related Essays
- Banking Panics of 1931-33
- Stock Market Crash of 1987
- The Great Depression
Related People
George L. Harrison President
New York Fed
1928 – 1940
IMAGES
VIDEO