Banner

  • Research Guides

ECON 3P01: History of Economic Thought I

  • Essay Writing
  • The Successful Research Process
  • Find Background Info
  • Find Primary Sources
  • Find Journal Articles

Essay Writing Guides and Tips

  • Cite Your Sources

Academic Writing Centre Guides

  • Student Resources (A-Z Learning Services, Brock University) Click on Essay Writing link to view guides and handouts such as a detailed essay template: getting started, organizing your paper, and a revisions checklist.
  • How to use sources (Trent University Academic Skills) Referencing Sources and Avoiding Plagiarism
  • How to Write in University (Trent University Academic Skills) - offers a variety of guides to writing in university including essay writing.
  • A Brief Guide to Writing the History Paper (Harvard College Writing Center) PDF handout
  • Writing about History (University of Toronto Writing Advice) Discusses primary and secondary sources; questions to consider when reading primary historical documents; and how to develop a manageable topic.

Online Books (A Selective List):

history of economic thought essay questions

  • << Previous: Find Journal Articles
  • Next: Cite Your Sources >>
  • Last Updated: Jul 14, 2023 3:56 PM
  • URL: https://researchguides.library.brocku.ca/econ3p01

History of Economic Thought

  • Living reference work entry
  • First Online: 14 December 2016
  • Cite this living reference work entry

history of economic thought essay questions

  • Craufurd D. Goodwin 2  

272 Accesses

11 Citations

Attention was paid to the history of economic thought (HET) by pioneers of economics such as Dupont de Nemours and Adam Smith. Classical economists like J.R. McCulloch in the 19th century used HET to establish a canon of economic literature, and their successor marginalists such as William Stanley Jevons to demonstrate progress in the subject. From the First World War until the 1960s, leading economists, from Jacob Viner to Wesley Mitchell, employed HET to cast light on current research. In the 1970s HET became a separate sub-discipline with its own periodicals and meetings. The number of scholars who worked in HET did not decline, even though the major research and postgraduate training centres lost interest.

This chapter was originally published in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics , 2nd edition, 2008. Edited by Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Bibliography

Ashley, W.J. 1894. An introduction to english economic history and theory . 3rd edn. London: Longmans Green.

Google Scholar  

Backhouse, R.E. 2000. Early histories of economic thought 1824–1914 . London: Routledge.

Backhouse, R.E. 2004. History of economics, economics and economic history in Britain, 1824–2000. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 11: 107–124.

Article   Google Scholar  

Barber, W. 1967. A history of economic thought . New York: Penguin.

Blanqui, A. 1837. Histoire de L’Economie Politique . Paris: Guillamin.

Blaug, M. 1962. Economic theory in retrospect . Homewood: Irwin.

Blaug, M. 1991. The historiography of economics . Aldershot: Edward Elgar.

Böhm-Bawerk, E.V. 1973. The Austrian economists. In Dictionary of the history of ideas , ed. P. Wiener. New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons.

Brems, H. 1986. Pioneering economic theory, 1630–1980 . Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Caldwell, B. 2004. Hayek’s challenge . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Cannan, E. 1917. A history of the theories of production and distribution in english political economy 1776–1848 , 1994. Bristol: Thoemmes.

Cole, A.H. 1957. The historical development of economic and business literature . Boston: Harvard Graduate School of Business Administration.

Cossa, L. 1876. Guida allo studio dell ’ economica politica . Milano: Ulrico Hoepli. (Eng. trans. 1880.)

Cournot, A. 1897. Researches into the mathematical principles of the theory of wealth , 1963. Homewood: Irwin.

Du Pont De Nemours. 1768. De L’Origine et des progrès d’une science nouvelle , 1910. Paris: Geuthner.

Eckland, R.B., and R.F. Hebert. 1975. A history of economic theory and method . New York: McGraw-Hill.

Gide, P.H.C., and C. Rist. 1909. Histoire des doctrines économiques . Paris: L. Larose and L. Tenin.

Gray, A. 1931. The development of economic doctrine . London: Longmans Green.

Gronewegen, P.D. 1995. A soaring eagle . London: Edward Elgar.

Haberler, G. 1937. Prosperity and depression . Geneva: League of Nations.

Haney, L. 1911. History of economic thought . New York: Macmillan.

Heilbroner, R. 1953. The worldly philosophers . New York: Simon and Schuster.

Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and capital . Oxford: Clarendon Press.

Hollander, S. 1973. The economics of Adam Smith . Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Hollander, S. 1979. The economics of David Ricardo . Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Hollander, S. 1985. The economics of John Stuart Mill . Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Hollander, S. 1996. The economics of Thomas Robert Malthus . Toronto: University of Toronto Press.

Ingram, J.K. 1888. A history of political economy, with a preface by E.J. James . New York: Macmillan.

Jevons, W.S. 1871. The theory of political economy , 1965. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

Keynes, J.M. 1919. Economic consequences of the peace , 1920. New York: Harcourt Brace.

Klein, J. 1997. Statistical visions in time . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Knight, F. 1956. On the history and method of economics . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Knight, F. 1973. Economic history. In Dictionary of the history of ideas , ed. P. Wiener. New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons.

Kuhn, T.S. 1962. The structure of scientific revolutions . Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Lakatos, I., and A. Musgrave. 1970. Criticism and the growth of knowledge . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Book   Google Scholar  

Landreth, H. 1976. History of economic thought . Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

Marget, A.W. 1938–1942. The theory of prices . New York: Prentice-Hall.

Marshall, A. 1920. Principles of economics . 8th edn, 1964. London: Macmillan.

McCloskey, D. 1998. The rhetoric of economics . 2nd edn. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

McCulloch, J.R. 1825. The principles of political economy , 1830. London: William.

McCulloch, J.R. 1845. The literature of political economy , 1938. London: London School of Economics and Political Science.

Menger, C. 1950. Principles of economics . Trans. and ed. J. Dingwall and B.F. Hoselitz. Glencoe: Free Press.

Mill, J.S. 1848. In Principles of political economy , ed. W.J. Ashley, 1909. London: Longmans.

Mirowski, P. 1989. More heat than light . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Mitchell, W.C. 1967. Types of economic theory . New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

Moggridge, D. 1992. Maynard Keynes: An economist’s biography . New York: Routledge.

Morgan, M. 1990. The history of econometric ideas . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Niehans, J. 1990. A history of economic theory . Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Price, L.L. 1891. A short history of political economy in England, from Adam Smith to Arnold Toynbee . London: Methuen.

Rima, I. 1967. Development of economic analysis . Homewood: R.D. Irwin.

Samuelson, P.A. 1947. Foundations of economic analysis . Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Schumpeter, J.A. 1954. History of economic analysis . New York: Oxford University Press.

Senior, N. 1827. An introductory lecture on political economy . London: J. Mawman.

Sent, E.-M. 1998. The evolving rationality of rational expectations . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Smith, A. 1776. An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations , 1976. Oxford: Clarendon.

Spengler, J.J. 1942. French predecessors of Malthus . Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

Spiegel, H. 1971. The growth of economic thought . Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

Stark, W. 1994. History and historians of political economy . New Brunswick: Transaction.

Stigler, G.J. 1941. Production and distribution theories, 1870 to 1895 . New York: Macmillan.

Strachey, L. 1918. Eminent victorians . London: Chatto and Windus.

Twiss, T. 1847. View of the progress of political economy in Europe since the sixteenth century . London: Longman.

Villeneuve-Bargemont, J.-P.-A. 1841. Histoire de l’économie politique . Paris: Guillaumin.

Viner, J. 1937. Studies in the theory of international trade , 1955. London: George Allen and Unwin.

Weintraub, E.R., ed. 2002a. The future of the history of economics . Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

Weintraub, E.R. 2002b. How economics became a mathematical science . Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

http://link.springer.com/referencework/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5

Craufurd D. Goodwin

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Editor information

Editors and affiliations, copyright information.

© 2008 The Author(s)

About this entry

Cite this entry.

Goodwin, C.D. (2008). History of Economic Thought. In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_2624-1

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_2624-1

Received : 09 September 2016

Accepted : 09 September 2016

Published : 14 December 2016

Publisher Name : Palgrave Macmillan, London

Online ISBN : 978-1-349-95121-5

eBook Packages : Springer Reference Economics and Finance Reference Module Humanities and Social Sciences Reference Module Business, Economics and Social Sciences

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research

history of economic thought essay questions

  • Submit content
  • Subscribe to content
  • Orientation
  • Participate

history of economic thought essay questions

History of Economic Thought

Related content,     exploring economics for teachers.

 Exploring Economics collects course descriptions, syllabi and slides so that lecturers can share resources and innovate their teaching.

Share your Syllabus          Find more Teaching Material     

This syllabus was originally taught at the University of Greenwich Winter Semester 2019. Instructor: Dr. Jeff Powell and Dr. Yuliya Yurchenko

Course Summary

The module is designed to first present some of the main schools of thought from a historical and methodological perspective.

Each week we explore and critically assess the main tenants of each school of thought. In the second part of the module we link history of economic thought and methodology to a specific and contemporary economic question. The second part allows you to engage with current economic issues with an awareness of methodology and methodological differences and with some knowledge of the history of economics. This course offers a critical historical and methodological introduction to the study of economics. The aim of this course is to equip students with tools to exercise their own judgment as economists. In particular, the discussion of the nature and scope of economics, with examples from history, is important in order to give students a sense of the economic discipline, its historical and methodological evolution, and to adequately address current economic issues. This course provides students with an understanding of the development of economics as a social science. It analyses various economic questions from a pluralistic perspective, i.e. it will consider different approaches to key economic issues.

On successful completion of this course a student will be able to:

  • Explain the historical and methodological development of economics from the 19th century to present day
  • Interpret and synthetize the contributions made by major authors in the history of economic thought
  • Explain the origins of some of the key concepts in contemporary economics
  • Evaluate key mainstream (neoclassical) and heterodox (non-neoclassical) economic theories and policies
  •  Analyse contemporary economic questions from a pluralistic perspective
  •  Master critical thinking and exercise judgment in economics by criticising and defending intellectual positions

Assignments and Assessment

You have to give in an Response paper wich counts up to 1500 words and weights 45% of your grade, also you have to write an Essay with up to 2000 words which counts 55% of your grade.

Course Overview

Schedule of topics covered and mandatory readings, session 1 (lecture) introduction to the course .

  • Familiarise with the course: aims and objectives, learning and teaching activities, and topics
  • Assessment and deadlines
  • Why study and teach history of economic thought?
  • Some important definitions: methodological pluralism, positivism, heterodox and orthodox economics, mainstream economics

Literature: 

  • BLAUG, Mark (2001). “No History of Ideas, Please, We are Economists”. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 15, No.1, pp. 145-164
  • DOW, Sheila (2009). “History of Thought and Methodology in Pluralist Economics Education”. International Review of Economics Education, Vol. 8, Issue 2, pp. 41-57

Session 1 (Seminar) Pluralism in Economics

  • Rethinking economics
  • Defining pluralism
  • Why is pluralism important in economics?
  • Review of key definitions
  • International Student Initiative for Pluralism in Economics (2014), Open Letter, “An international student call for pluralism in economics”. Wesleyan
  • KING, John E. (2002). “Three arguments for Pluralism in Economics”. Journal of Australian Political Economy, pp. 82-87.7

Session 2 (Lecture) Classical Political Economy 

Content: 

  • Adam Smith and the framework of classical analysis
  • From moral philosophy to Political Economy
  • Utilitarianism and the Philosophic Radicals
  • Ricardian Economics
  • Alternative to Ricardian Economics
  • John Stuart Mill
  • BARBER, William J. (2009). Chapter 1, “Adam Smith and the Framework of Classical Analysis” pp. 23-51. Book title: A History of Economic Thought.
  • BACKHOUSE, Roger E. (2002). Chapter 7, “Classical Political Economy, 1790–1870”, pages 132–157 (i.e. from section titled “From Moral Philosophy to Political Economy” to section “John Stuart Mill” included). Book title: The Penguin History of Economics. Penguin Books.

Session 2 (Seminar) Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiment (TMS)

  • What are the main arguments raised in the TMS?
  • A feminist critique of TMS: the construction of masculine identity in TMS
  • Neoliberalism, TMS and The Wealth of Nations
  • HANLEY, Christopher (2015). “Neoliberalism, emotional experience in education and Adam Smith: reading The theory of moral sentiments alongside The wealth of nations”. Journal of Educational Administration and History. Vol. 47, Issue 2, pp.105-116
  • FOLBRE, Nancy (2009). "The Butcher, the Banker, and the Wife". Ch.4 (Free Trade but not Free Love), pp. 58-61. Greed, Lust and Gender. A History of Economic Ideas. Oxford University Press.

Session 3 (Lecture) Marxian Economics 

  • Marx and the classical tradition
  • The analysis of value
  • The concepts of surplus value, variable capital, and constant capital
  • The analysis of accumulation
  • The analysis of distribution
  • BARBER, William J. (2009). Part Two “Introduction” and Chapter 5 “Karl Marx and the economics of Das Kapital” pp. 124-151. Book title: A History of Economic Thought. Wesleyan.
  • BACKHOUSE, Roger E. (2002). Chapter 7, “Classical Political Economy, 1790–1870”, pages 156–164 (i.e. section “Karl Marx”). Book title: The Penguin History of Economics. Penguin Books.
  • Optional reading useful for response paper: RONCAGLIA (2009), Ch. 9 Karl Marx, in particular section “the critique of the division of labour: alienation and commodity fetishism”. Book title: The Wealth of Ideas. Cambridge University Press

Session 3 (Seminar) Marx: Imperalism and Capitalist Development

  • What is economic imperialism?
  • Dynamics of capital accumulation
  • Primitive accumulation
  • PRADELLA, Lucia (2013). “Imperialism and capitalist development in Marx’s Capital”. Historical Materialism, 21.2, pp. 117-147

Session 4 (Lecture) The two Ruptures in Economic Thought 

  • Smith, Riccardo and the first rupture in economic thought (inductive/ historical and deductive abstract methods)
  • Movement from classical political economy to neoclassical economics (marginalist revolution)
  • MILONAKIS, Dimitris and Ben FINE (2009). Chapter 2 “Smith, Riccardo and the first rupture in economic thought” and Chapter 6 “Marginalism and the Methodenstreit”. Book title: From Political Economy to Economics. Routledge.

 Session 4 (Seminar) Methodological Individualism and Self-Interest 

  • What is methodological individualism?
  • Self-interest and status in classical political economy
  • Self-interest in neoclassical economics
  • Self-interest and gender
  • KERN, William S. (2001). “Classical Economic Man: Was it Interested in Keeping up with the Joneses?” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Vol. 23, No. 3, pp.353 – 368
  • FOLBRE, Nancy and HARTMANN, Heidi (1988). Chapter 12, “The Rhetoric of self-interest: ideology and gender in economic theory”. Edited book info: MCKLOSKEY, Donald, Robert  SOLOW, Arjo KLAMER, “The Consequences of Economic Rhetoric”. Cambridge University Press.

Session 5 (Lecture) Neoclassical Economics 

  • Alfred Marshal
  • Leon Walras
  • American strand of early neo-classicism
  • The Austrian school
  • BARBER, William J. (2009). Part 3 “Introduction”, Chapter 6 “Alfred Marshall and the Framework of Neo-Classical Economics”, Chapter 7 “Pre-1914 Variations on Neo-Classical Themes” pp. 168-221. Book title: A History of Economic Thought. Wesleyan.

Session 5 (Seminar) Neoclassical Economics and Reality 

  • Core assumptions stemming from neoclassical economics
  • Critique of conventional economic theory
  • KEEN, Steve (2011). Part 1 “The Logical Flaws in the key concepts of conventional economics”, p.37 and pp. 41-57 (i.e. from section “Flaws in the glass” to section” Drawing the results” included).

Session 6 (Lecture) Keynesian Economics 

  • Keynes’s General Theory
  • Attack on Say’s Law and the interpretation of money
  • Savings, consumption and investment
  • Aggregate equilibrium
  • Theory of employment
  • BARBER, William J. (2009). Part Four “Introduction”, Chapter 8 “The Economics of Keynes’s General Theory” pp. 223-258. Book title: A History of Economic Thought. Wesleyan. MINSKY, Hyman (2008). Chapter 1 “The General Theory and its Interpretation”. Book title: John Maynard Keynes. McGraw Hill

Session 6 (Seminar) Keynes' Uncertainty & The Global Crisis

  • Risk and uncertainty
  • Keynesian view of the global economic crisis
  • SKIDELSKY, Robert (2011). “The relevance of Keynes”. Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 35, Issue 1, pp.-13

Session 7 (Lecture) Modern Economics: The Age of Fragmentation 

  • General Economic Equilibrium
  • New theories of the firm
  • Institutional and economic theory
  • Macro theory after Keynes
  • RONCAGLIA, Alessandro (2009). Chapter 17 “The Age of Fragmentation”. Book title: The Wealth of Ideas. A History of Economic Thought. Cambridge University Press.

Session 7 (Seminar) Mainstream & Heterodox Economics 

  • What is mainstream and what is heterodox economics?
  • What are the characteristics of heterodox economics?
  • Is mainstream economics the same as neoclassical economics?
  • LEE, Frederic (2009). “Introduction”. Book title: “A history of heterodox economics”. Routledge
  • COLANDER, David (2000). “The death of neoclassical economics”. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Vol.21, No.2, pp.127-143

Session 8 (Lecture) The Role of the State in Economics 

  • Role of the state in historical perspective
  • Smith, Mill, Pigou, Coase, Keynes, Marx
  • CHANG, Ha-Joon (2004) Chapter 1 “Theories of state intervention in historical perspective”. Book info: Globalization, economic Development and the role of the state. Zed Books.

Session 8 (Seminar) The Entrepreneurical State 

  • What is the role of the state in economics?
  • Can the state support innovation and technological development?
  • MAZZUCATO, Mariana (2016). Chapter 5 “Innovation, the state and patient capital”. Edited book info: JACOBS, Michael and Mariana, MAZZUCATO (eds) Rethinking Capitalism. Wiley Blackwell.
  • KRUEGER, Anne (1990). “Government failures in development”. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 4, Issue 3, pp. 9-23.

Session 9 (Lecture) What are the Causes of Unemployment? 

  • Neoclassical explanation for unemployment
  • Keynes and involuntary unemployment
  • Marx’s reserve army labour
  • Is full employment possible?
  • SPENCER, David (2006) “Work for all those who want it? Why the neoclassical labour supply curve is an inappropriate foundation for the theory of employment and unemployment?”. Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 30, Issue 3, pp.459-472.
  • POLLIN, Robert (2008) “Is full employment possible under globalization?” PERI Working Paper Series, No. 141, Revised April 2008

Session 9 (Seminar) Unemployment and the Great Recession 

  • Labour market policies during the great recession
  •  Alternative approches to deal with unemployment
  • MAGDOFF, Fred and Harry, MAGDOF (2004). “Disposable workers. Today’s reserve army of labour”. Monthly Review, Vol. 55, Issue 11, pp.18-35.
  • BLANCHARD, Oliver JAROTTE, Florence LOUNGAN, Prakash (2013) “Labour Market Policies and IMF advice in advanced economies during the great recession”. IMF Staff discussion note. March 29.

Session 10 (Lecture) What causes Economic Crises? 

  • Neoclassical and New Keynesian interpretations
  • Standard interpretation using Keynes
  • Minsky’s Financial Instability Hypothesis
  • Marxian theories of crisis
  • MINSKY, Hyman (1992). “The Financial Instability Hypothesis”. Working Paper No.74, Levy Economics Institute.
  • WHALLEN, Charles (2007). The US Credit Crunch of 2007. A Minsky Moment. Levy Institute Policy Brief

Session 10 (Seminar) Alernative Interpretations of the Crisis 

  • Causes and dynamics of the current crisis from different perspectives
  • CALOMIRIS, Charles (2008). “The subprime turmoil: what’s old, what’s new, what’s next?”. International Monetary Fund (IMF), Paper presented at the 9th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference, 13-14 Nov 2008.] EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ONLY.
  • RSA video: David Harvey on the crises of capitalism

Session 11 (Lecture) How should we respond to Crises? The Political Economy of Austerity 

  • Classical debate on austerity
  • Treasury view
  • Expansionary fiscal contraction
  • KONZELMANN, Suzanne (2014). “The Political Economy of Austerity”. Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 38, Issue 4, pp.701-741.
  • KELTON, Stephanie (2016). Chapter 2 “The failure of austerity: rethinking fiscal policy”. Edited book info: JACOBS, Michael and Mariana, MAZZUCATO (eds) Rethinking Capitalism. Wiley Blackwell.

Session 11 (Seminar) The Policy Approach to Austerity 

  • How has the political economy of austerity influenced current economic policies?
  • What are possible alternatives to austerity policies?
  • What is the role of investment for economic recovery?
  • STIGLITZ, Joseph (2012). “Stimulating the economy in an era of debt and deficit”. Columbia University Academic Commons.
  • European Commission (2015). “Making the best use of the flexibility within the existing rules of the Stability and Growth Pact”. COM(2015) final, 13 January, 2015.

Session 12 Summing up: The Rethoric of Economics 

  • The importance of conversation and critical analysis in economics 
  • McCLOSKEY, Donald (1983). “The Rhetoric of economics”. Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 21, Issue 2, pp.434-461

Recommended Recources 

Textbooks: .

  • HUNT, H.K. and Mark LAUTZENHEISHER (2011) "History of Economic Thought. A Critical Perspective". Routledge
  • MILONAKIS, Dimitris and Ben FINE (2009) "From Political Economy to Economics". Routledge
  • RONCAGLIA, Alessandro (2009) "The Wealth of Ideas. A History of Economic Thought". Cambridge University Press

Useful Online Resources: 

  • The history of economic thought website : here you can find an alphabetical index of individual economists, pages covering various schools of thought and a series of essays and surveys on specific topics;
  •   INET History of Economic Thought : here you can find useful resources ranging from articles, videos, conference proceedings. The website provides some good critical reflections on history of economic thought and contemporary economics;
  • European Society for the History of Economic Thought : a website where you can find lots of publications on History of Economic Thought, events, and researchers working on the subject.
  • Rethinking economics : the international network of students, thinkers and citizens coming together to invigorate economics. You will find interesting articles, videos and other materials on rethinking economics.

Academic Journals:

Below you can find a list of academic journal where you can search and find additional material on History of Economic thought. Articles in academic journals tend to be more technical and complex. All these journals are available via the University of Greenwich Library site.

  • History of Political Economy
  • Journal of the History of Economic Thought
  • History of Economic Ideas
  • The Economic History Review

 Stay tuned!

Subscribe to our newsletter to learn about new debates, conferences and writing workshops.

Volkswirtschaftslehre als Indoktrination und die (Nicht-)Auswirkungen der Finanzkrise

This project is brought to you by the Network for Pluralist Economics ( Netzwerk Plurale Ökonomik e.V. ).  It is committed to diversity and independence and is dependent on donations from people like you. Regular or one-off donations would be greatly appreciated.

  • Request Info

Waidner-Spahr Library

  • Do Research
  • About the Library
  • Dickinson Scholar
  • Ask a Librarian
  • My Library Account

Economics: History of Economic Thought

  • Books & Films
  • Statistics & Data
  • History of Economic Thought
  • Related Research Guides

Oxford English Dictionary & Historical Thesaurus

  • OED (Oxford English Dictionary) This link opens in a new window Explore the evolution of the English language and the meaning, history, and pronunciation of English words, past and present. Under each term, definitions are listed in chronological order according to quotation evidence (earliest known usage). Coverage: historical and current. Full text.

Background Information on Economics Topics

  • New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics This link opens in a new window Explore economics topics, concepts, and people, with entries written by leading scholars in the field. Coverage: varies. Full text.
  • Credo Reference This link opens in a new window Access encyclopedic titles in all disciplines taught at Dickinson, including various language dictionaries, the Marquis Who's Who series and numerous other biographical sources, economics and business encyclopedias, food and agriculture sources, publishing sources, atlases, and many encyclopedias covering the arts, history, literature, science, technology, religion, philosophy, politics, psychology, geography, country studies, and more. Coverage: varies. Full text.
  • Routledge Handbook of Feminist Economics by Berik, Günseli, and Ebru Kongar Call Number: online Publication Date: 2021 Presents a comprehensive overview of the contributions of feminist economics to the discipline of economics and beyond. Each chapter situates the topic within the history of the field, reflects upon current debates, and looks forward to identify cutting-edge research. The contributors are a diverse mix of established and rising scholars of feminist economics from around the globe who skillfully frame the current state and future direction of feminist economic scholarship.

Food for Thought

  • Why Economics Needs Economic History In this article, Kevin H O’Rourke Professor of Economic History at University of Oxford, explains why economic history remains relevant to today's societal concerns.

Related Research Guide

  • Historical Newspapers Guide Links to U.S. and International historic newspaper collections.

Primary Sources on History of Economic Thought

  • American Periodicals Series Online 1740-1900 This link opens in a new window Access over 1,500 periodicals that first began publishing between 1740 and 1900, including special interest and general magazines, literary and professional journals, children's and women's magazines; 89 journals published between 1740 and 1800 offer insights into America's transition from colonial times to independence; and 118 periodicals published during the Civil War (1861-1865) and Reconstruction (1865-1877) eras; and many other historically-significant periodicals. Coverage: 1740-1900, contains primary sources. Full text.
  • Early American Newspapers, 1690-1928 This link opens in a new window Explore fully searchable historical newspapers from all 50 states. Searches can be limited by date range, article type, language, place of publication, and newspaper title. Coverage: 1690-1922, contains primary sources. Full text.
  • Economist Historical Archive This link opens in a new window Access historical Economist news magazine issues, including supplements, special reports, surveys, full-color images, exportable financial tables, and a gallery of front covers. This magazine is cross-searchable with other collections via Gale Primary Sources . Coverage: 1843-2020, contains primary sources. Full text.
  • Eighteenth-Century Collections Online (ECCO) This link opens in a new window Access works catalogued in the eighteenth-century section of the English Short-Title Catalogue. The collection includes a wide variety of materials from books and directories, Bibles, sheet music and sermons to advertisements and works by many well-known and lesser-known authors. It is cross-searchable with other collections via Gale Primary Sources . Coverage: 18th century, contains primary sources. Full text.
  • History of Economic Thought (On Campus Access) This link opens in a new window *This link provides access from on campus only.* Explore the history of economic thought over the period 1700–1914. This collection contains primary and secondary resources, including full books, selected chapters, and journal articles, as well as new thematic essays, and subject introductions on key themes. Coverage: varies, contains primary sources. Full text. This purchase was a gift of the Walter E. Beach Library Fund.
  • History of Economic Thought (Remote Access) This link opens in a new window *This link provides remote access only.* Explore the history of economic thought over the period 1700–1914. This collection contains primary and secondary resources, including full books, selected chapters, and journal articles, as well as new thematic essays, and subject introductions on key themes. Coverage: varies, contains primary sources. Full text. This purchase was a gift of the Walter E. Beach Library Fund.
  • U.K. Parliamentary Papers This link opens in a new window Access official British government documents from the 18th, 19th, and 20th centuries. Coverage: contains primary sources. Full text. See ProQuest's guide to searching this platform.
  • Library of Economics & Liberty Full-text of classic works on economic thought, as well as articles on contemporary economics topics. Maintained by the Liberty Fund, Inc., a private, educational foundation.
  • Making of America (U. of Michigan) This link opens in a new window Access primary sources in American social history from the antebellum period through reconstruction. This collection is particularly strong in the subject areas of education, psychology, American history, sociology, religion, and science and technology. Coverage: 19th century, contains primary sources. Full text.
  • Making of the Modern World This link opens in a new window Includes books, journals, pamphlets, essays, reports, correspondence, speeches, surveys. Content is in English and other languages. Provides historical access to the theories, practices, and consequences of economic and business activity in the West. Coverage: 1450 - 1963, contains primary sources. Full-Text. database demo (4 min. video) Includes the Goldsmiths-Kress Collection.
  • McMaster University Archive for the History of Economic Thought "...an attempt to collect in one place a large number of significant texts in the history of economic thought."
  • Gale Primary Sources This link opens in a new window Search across primary source collections including Eighteenth Century Collections Online, Nineteenth Century Collections Online, Making of the Modern World, Indigenous Peoples: North America, Archives Unbound, Archives of Sexuality and Gender, Associated Press Collections, as well as a variety of periodical archives including: Nineteenth Century British Library Newspapers; Nineteenth Century United States Newspapers; Financial Times; The Economist; Liberty Magazine, 1924-1950; The Listener, 1929-1991; The Sunday Times (London); The Telegraph; The Times (London); and The Times (London) Literary Supplement. Coverage: 19th-21st centuries, contains primary sources. Full text.
  • (1) Asia & the West: Diplomacy & Cultural Exchange includes government reports, diplomatic correspondence, periodicals, newspapers, treaties, trade agreements, NGO papers, & more.
  • (2) British Politics & Society includes sources related to the political climate in Great Britain.
  • (3) British Theatre, Music, & Literature: High & Popular Culture includes primary sources such as playbills, scripts to operas & complete scores.
  • (4) Children's Literature & Childhood includes books & periodicals for children.
  • (5) Europe & Africa: Commerce, Christianity, Civilization, & Conquest includes monographs, periodicals, & other materials documenting European policies & their effects in Africa.
  • (6) European Literature, 1790-1840: The Corvey Collection includes English, French & German titles including fiction, short prose, dramatic works, poetry & more, with a focus on difficult-to-find works by historically neglected writers.
  • (7) Mapping the World: Maps & Travel Literature includes battle and boundary maps, fictional travel narratives, guidebooks, pamphlets, trail and road maps, and more.
  • (8) Photography: The World through the Lens, includes photos & publications about photography.
  • (9) Religion, Reform, and Society includes periodicals, monographs, family papers, society records, and other religious publications.
  • (10-11) Science, Technology & Medicine: 1780-1925, parts 1-2 include journals, books & other documents.
  • (12) Women: Transnational Networks includes journals, books, manuscripts, & other materials, mostly from the U.S. & U.K., but with some other countries as well.
  • Telegraph Historical Archive, 1855-2016 This link opens in a new window Access historical pages of the popular London Telegraph newspaper’s archive, including its Sunday edition. This newspaper is cross-searchable with other collections via Gale Primary Sources . Coverage: 1855-2016, contains primary sources. Full text.
  • << Previous: Statistics & Data
  • Next: Related Research Guides >>
  • Last Updated: Feb 5, 2024 10:24 AM
  • URL: https://libguides.dickinson.edu/economics

history of economic thought essay questions

Plato and his pupil Aristotle had an enduring effect on Western philosophy .

Ancient Athens , an advanced city-state civilization and progressive society, developed an embryonic model of democracy. [7]

Xenophon ‘s (c. 430–354 BC) Oeconomicus (c. 360 BC) is a dialogue principally about household management and agriculture.

Plato ‘s dialogue The Republic (c. 380–360 BC) describing an ideal city-state run by philosopher-kings contained references to specialization of labor and to production . According to Joseph Schumpeter , Plato was the first known advocate of a credit theory of money that is, money as a unit of account for debt. [8]

Aristotle ‘s Politics (c. 350 BC) analyzed different forms of the state ( monarchy , aristocracy , constitutional government , tyranny , oligarchy , and democracy ) as a critique of Plato’s model of a philosopher-kings. Of particular interest for economists, Plato provided a blueprint of a society based on common ownership of resources. Aristotle viewed this model as an oligarchical anathema . Though Aristotle did certainly advocate holding many things in common, he argued that not everything could be, simply because of the “wickedness of human nature”. [9]

“It is clearly better that property should be private”, wrote Aristotle, “but the use of it common; and the special business of the legislator is to create in men this benevolent disposition.” In Politics Book I, Aristotle discusses the general nature of households and market exchanges. For him there is a certain “art of acquisition” or “wealth-getting”, but because it  is the same many people are obsessed with its accumulation, and “wealth-getting” for one’s household is “necessary and honorable”, while exchange on the retail trade for simple accumulation is “justly censured, for it is dishonorable”. [10] Writing of the people, Aristotle stated that they as a whole thought acquisition of wealth ( chrematistike ) as being either the same as, or a principle of oikonomia (“household management” – oikonomos ), [11] [12] with oikos meaning “house” and with ( themis meaning “custom”) nomos meaning “law”. [13] Aristotle himself highly disapproved of usury and cast scorn on making money through a monopoly . [14]

Aristotle discarded Plato’s credit theory of money for metallism , the theory that money derives its value from the purchasing power of the commodity upon which it is based, and is only an “instrument”, its sole purpose being a medium of exchange, which means on its own “it is worthless… not useful as a means to any of the necessities of life”. [15]

Economic thought in the Middle Ages (500–1500 AD)

history of economic thought essay questions

Thomas Aquinas (1225–1274) taught that high prices in response to high demand is theft.

Thomas Aquinas

Thomas Aquinas (1225–1274) was an Italian theologian and economic writer. He taught in both Cologne and Paris  and was part of a group of Catholic scholars known as the Schoolmen , who moved their inquiries beyond theology to philosophical and scientific debates. In the treatise, Summa Theologica Aquinas  dealt with the concept of a just price , which he considered necessary for the reproduction of the social order. Similar in many ways to the modern concept of long-run equilibrium , a just price was just sufficient to cover the costs of production , including the maintenance of a worker and his family. Aquinas argued it was immoral for sellers to raise their prices simply because buyers had a pressing need for a product.

Aquinas discusses a number of topics in the format of questions and replies, substantial tracts dealing with Aristotle’s theory. Questions 77 and 78 concern economic issues, primarily what a just price might be, and the fairness of a seller dispensing faulty goods. Aquinas argued against any form of cheating and recommended always paying compensation in lieu of good service [ clarification needed ] . Whilst human laws might not impose sanctions for unfair dealing, divine law did, in his opinion.

Duns Scotus

history of economic thought essay questions

Duns Scotus (1265–1308)

One of Aquinas’ main critics [16] was Duns Scotus (1265–1308), originally from Duns Scotland, who taught in Oxford, Cologne, and Paris. In his work Sententiae (1295), he thought it possible to be more precise than Aquinas in calculating a just price, emphasizing the costs of labor and expenses, although he recognized that the latter might be inflated by exaggeration because buyer and seller usually have different ideas of a just price. If people did not benefit from a transaction, in Scotus’ view, they would not trade. Scotus said merchants perform a necessary and useful social role by transporting goods and making them available to the public. [16]

Jean Buridan

Jean Buridan ( French:  [byʁidɑ̃] ; Latin Johannes Buridanus ; c. 1300 – after 1358) was a French priest . Buridanus looked at money from two angles: its metal value and its purchasing power, which he acknowledged can vary. He argued that aggregated, not individual, demand and supply determine market prices. Hence, for him a just price was what the society collectively and not just one individual is willing to pay.

Ibn Khaldun [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Ibn Khaldun (1332–1406)

Until Joseph J. Spengler ‘s 1964 work “Economic Thought of Islam: Ibn Khaldun”, [18] Adam Smith (1723–1790) was considered the “Father of Economics”. Now there is a second candidate, Arab Muslim scholar Ibn Khaldun (1332–1406) of Tunisia, although what influence Khaldun had in the West is unclear. Arnold Toynbee called Ibn Khaldun a “genius” who “appears to have been inspired by no predecessors and to have found no kindred souls among his contemporaries…and yet, in the Prolegomena ( Muqaddimat ) to his Universal History he has conceived and formulated a philosophy of history which is undoubtedly the greatest work of its kind that has ever yet been created by any mind in any time or place.” [19] Ibn Khaldoun expressed a theory of the lifecycle of civilizations, the specialization of labor, and the value of money as a means of exchange rather than as a store of inherent value. His ideas on taxes bore a striking resemblance to supply-side economics ‘ Laffer curve , which posits that beyond a certain point higher taxes discourage production and actually cause revenues to fall. [20]

Nicole Oresme

history of economic thought essay questions

Nicolas d’Oresme (1320–82)

French philosopher and priest Nicolas d’Oresme (1320–1382) wrote De origine, natura, jure et mutationibus monetarum , about the origin, nature, law, and alterations of money. It is one of the earliest manuscripts on the concept of money.

Antonin of Florence

Saint Antoninus of Florence (1389–1459), O.P. , was an Italian Dominican friar , who became Archbishop of Florence . Antoninus’ writings address social and economic development and argued that the state has a duty to intervene in mercantile affairs for the common good, and an obligation to help the poor and needy. In his primary work, “summa theologica” he was mainly concerned about price, justice and capital theory. Like Duns Scotus , he distinguishes between the natural value of a good and its practical value. The latter is determined by its suitability to satisfy needs (virtuositas), its rarity (raritas) and its subjective value (complacibilitas). Due to this subjective component there can not only be one just price, but a bandwidth of more or less just prices.

Mercantilism and international trade (16th to 18th century)

history of economic thought essay questions

Marquis de Mirabeau (1715–1789)

Mercantilism dominated Europe from the 16th to the 18th century. [21] Despite the localism of the Middle Ages, the waning of feudalism saw new national economic frameworks begin to strengthen. After the 15th century voyages of Christopher Columbus and other explorers opened up new opportunities for trade with the New World and Asia, newly-powerful monarchies wanted a more powerful military state to boost their status. Mercantilism was a political movement and an economic theory that advocated the use of the state’s military power to ensure that local markets and supply sources were protected, spawning protectionism .

history of economic thought essay questions

French seaport during the heyday of mercantilism

Mercantile theorists held that international trade could not benefit all countries at the same time. Money and precious metals were the only source of riches in their view, and limited resources must be allocated between countries, therefore tariffs should be used to encourage exports, which bring money into the country, and discourage imports which send it abroad. In other words, a positive balance of trade ought to be maintained through a surplus of exports, often backed by military might. Despite the prevalence of the model, the term mercantilism was not coined until 1763, by Victor de Riqueti, marquis de Mirabeau (1715–1789), and popularized by Adam Smith in 1776, who vigorously opposed it.

School of Salamanca [ edit ]

In the 16th century the Jesuit School of Salamanca in Spain developed economic theory to a high level, only to have their contributions [ clarification needed ] forgotten until the 20th century.

Sir Thomas More [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Sir Thomas More (1478–1535)

In 1516 English humanist Sir Thomas More (1478–1535) published Utopia , which describes an ideal society where land is owned in common and there is universal education and religious tolerance, inspiring the English Poor Laws (1587) and the communism-socialism movement. [ citation needed ]

Nicolaus Copernicus [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Nicolaus Copernicus (1473–1543)

In 1517 astronomer Nicolaus Copernicus (1473–1543) published the first known argument for the quantity theory of money . In 1519 he also published the first known form of Gresham’s Law : “Bad money drives out good”.

Jean Bodin [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Jean Bodin (1530–1596)

In 1568 Jean Bodin (1530–1596) of France published Reply to Malestroit , containing the first known analysis of inflation , which he claimed was caused by importation of gold and silver from South America , backing the quantity theory of money .

Barthélemy de Laffemas [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Barthélemy de Laffemas (1545–1612)

In 1598 French mercantilist economist Barthélemy de Laffemas (1545–1612) published Les Trésors et richesses pour mettre l’Estat en splendeur , which blasted those who frowned on French silks because the industry created employment for the poor, the first known mention of underconsumption theory , which was later refined by John Maynard Keynes .

Leonardus Lessius [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Leonardus Lessius (1554–1623)

In 1605 Flemish Jesuit theologian Leonardus Lessius (1554–1623) published On Justice and Law , the deepest moral-theological study of economics since Aquinas, whose just price approach he claimed was no longer workable. After comparing money’s growth via avarice to the propagation of hares, he made the first statement of the price of insurance as being based on risk.

Edward Misselden and Gerard Malynes [ edit ]

In 1622 English merchants Edward Misselden and Gerard Malynes began a dispute over free trade and the desirability of government regulation of companies, with Malynes arguing against foreign exchange as under the control of bankers [ clarification needed ] , and Misselden arguing that international money exchange and fluctuations in the exchange rate depend upon international trade and not bankers, and that the state should regulate trade to insure export surpluses.

Thomas Mun [ edit ]

English economist Thomas Mun (1571–1641) describes early mercantilist policy in his book England’s Treasure by Foreign Trade , which was not published until 1664, although it was widely circulated in manuscript form during his lifetime. A member of the East India Company , he wrote about his experiences in A Discourse of Trade from England unto the East Indies (1621).

Sir William Petty [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Sir William Petty (1623–1687)

In 1662 English economist Sir William Petty (1623–1687) began publishing short works applying the rational scientific tradition of Francis Bacon to economics, requiring that it only use measurable phenomena and seek quantitative precision, coining the term “political arithmetic”, introducing statistical mathematics, and becoming the first scientific economist.

Philipp von Hörnigk [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

The title page to Philipp von Hörnigk ‘s statement of mercantilist philosophy.

Philipp von Hörnigk (1640–1712, sometimes spelt Hornick or Horneck ) was born in Frankfurt and became an Austrian civil servant writing in a time when his country was constantly threatened by Ottoman invasion . In Österreich Über Alles, Wann es Nur Will (1684, Austria Over All, If She Only Will ) he laid out one of the clearest statements of mercantile policy, listing nine principal rules of national economy:

To inspect the country’s soil with the greatest care, and not to leave the agricultural possibilities of a single corner or clod of earth unconsidered… All commodities found in a country, which cannot be used in their natural state, should be worked up within the country… Attention should be given to the population, that it may be as large as the country can support… gold and silver once in the country are under no circumstances to be taken out for any purpose… The inhabitants should make every effort to get along with their domestic products… [Foreign commodities] should be obtained not for gold or silver, but in exchange for other domestic wares… and should be imported in unfinished form, and worked up within the country… Opportunities should be sought night and day for selling the country’s superfluous goods to these foreigners in manufactured form… No importation should be allowed under any circumstances of which there is a sufficient supply of suitable quality at home.

Nationalism , self-sufficiency and national power were the basic policies proposed. [22]

Jean-Baptiste Colbert and Pierre Le Pesant, Sieur de Boisguilbert [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Jean-Baptiste Colbert (1619–1683)

In 1665–1683 Jean-Baptiste Colbert (1619–1683) was minister of finance under King Louis XIV of France , and set up national guilds to regulate major industries. Silk , linen , tapestry , furniture manufacture and wine were examples of the crafts in which France specialized, all of which came to require membership in a guild to operate in until the French Revolution . According to Colbert, “It is simply and solely the abundance of money within a state [which] makes the difference in its grandeur and power.” [ citation needed ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Pierre Le Pesant, sieur de Boisguilbert (1646–1714)

In 1695 French economist Pierre Le Pesant, sieur de Boisguilbert (1646–1714) wrote a plea to Louis XIV to end Colbert’s mercantilist program, containing the first notion of an economical market , becoming the first economist to question mercantile economic policy and value the wealth of a country by its production and exchange of goods instead its assets.

Charles Davenant [ edit ]

In 1696 British mercantilist Tory Member of parliament Charles Davenant (1656–1714) published Essay on the East India Trade , displaying the first understanding of consumer demand and perfect competition .

Sir James Steuart [ edit ]

In 1767 Scottish mercantilist economist Sir James Steuart (1713–1780) published An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy , the first book in English with the term “political economy” in the title, and the first complete economics treatise.

Sir James Steuart (1713–1780)

history of economic thought essay questions

An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy , 1767

Mughal Emperor Aurangzeb [ edit ]

Emperor Aurangzeb , ruler of the Mughal India , compiled the sharia based Fatawa-e-Alamgiri along several Muslim scholars which include Islamic economics , [23] [24] whose policies eventually led to the period of Proto-industrialization . [25] [26] [27] It lasted as South Asia’s principal regulating body until the beginning of the 18th century. [28]

history of economic thought essay questions

The reign of Mughal emperor Aurangzeb in India may have been the initial period of the late modern Industrial revolution .

Pre-Classical (17th and 18th century) [ edit ]

The british enlightenment [ edit ].

In the 17th century Britain went through troubling times, enduring not only political and religious division in the English Civil War , King Charles I’s execution, and the Cromwellian dictatorship , but also the Great Plague of London and Great Fire of London . The restoration of the monarchy under Charles II , who had Roman Catholic sympathies, led to turmoil and strife, and his Catholic-leaning successor King James II was swiftly ousted. Invited in his place were Protestant William of Orange and Mary , who assented to the Bill of Rights 1689 , ensuring that the Parliament was dominant in what became known as the Glorious Revolution .

The upheaval was accompanied by a number of major scientific advances, including Robert Boyle ‘s discovery of the gas pressure constant (1660) and Sir Isaac Newton ‘s publication of Philosophiae Naturalis Principia Mathematica (1687), which described Newton’s laws of motion and his universal law of gravitation .

All these factors spurred the advancement of economic thought. For instance, Richard Cantillon (1680–1734) consciously imitated Newton’s forces of inertia and gravity in the natural world with human reason and market competition in the economic world. [29] In his Essay on the Nature of Commerce in General , he argued rational self-interest in a system of freely-adjusting markets would lead to order and mutually-compatible prices. Unlike the mercantilist thinkers however, wealth was found not in trade but in human labor . The first person to tie these ideas into a political framework was John Locke .

John Locke [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

John Locke (1632–1704) combined philosophy , politics and economics into one coherent framework.

John Locke (1632–1704) was born near Bristol , and educated in London and Oxford . He is considered one of the most significant philosophers of his era mainly for his critique of Thomas Hobbes ‘ defense of absolutism in Leviathan (1651) and of his social contract theory. Locke believed that people contracted into society, which was bound to protect their property rights. [30] He defined property broadly to include people’s lives and liberties, as well as their wealth. When people combined their labor with their surroundings, that created property rights. In his words from his Second Treatise on Civil Government (1689):

“God hath given the world to men in common… Yet every man has a property in his own person. The labour of his body and the work of his hands we may say are properly his. Whatsoever, then, he removes out of the state that nature hath provided and left it in, he hath mixed his labour with, and joined to it something that is his own, and thereby makes it his property.” [31]

Locke argued that not only should the government cease interference with people’s property (or their “lives, liberties and estates”), but also that it should positively work to ensure their protection. His views on price and money were laid out in a letter to a Member of Parliament in 1691 entitled Some Considerations on the Consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money (1691), arguing that the “price of any commodity rises or falls, by the proportion of the number of buyers and sellers”, a rule which “holds universally in all things that are to be bought and sold.” [32]

Dudley North [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Dudley North (1641–1691) argued that the results of mercantile policy are undesirable.

Dudley North (1641–1691) was a wealthy merchant and landowner who worked for Her Majesty’s Treasury and opposed most mercantile policy. His Discourses upon trade (1691), published anonymously, argued against assuming a need for a favorable balance of trade . Trade , he argued, benefits both sides, promotes specialization, division of labor and wealth for everyone. Regulation of trade interferes with these benefits, he said.

David Hume [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

David Hume (1711–76)

David Hume (1711–1776) agreed with North’s philosophy and denounced mercantilist assumptions. His contributions were set down in Political Discourses (1752), and later consolidated in his Essays, Moral, Political, Literary (1777). Adding to the argument that it was undesirable to strive for a favourable balance of trade , Hume argued that it is, in any case, impossible.

Hume held that any surplus of exports would be paid for by imports of gold and silver. This would increase the money supply , causing prices to rise. That in turn would cause a decline in exports until the balance with imports is restored.

Bernard Mandeville [ edit ]

Bernard Mandeville , (1670–1733), was an Anglo-Dutch philosopher, political economist and satirist. His main thesis is that the actions of men cannot be divided into lower and higher. The higher life of man is a mere fiction introduced by philosophers and rulers to simplify government and the relations of society. In fact, virtue (which he defined as “every performance by which man, contrary to the impulse of nature, should endeavour the benefit of others, or the conquest of his own passions, out of a rational ambition of being good”) is actually detrimental to the state in its commercial and intellectual progress. This is because it is the vices (i.e., the self-regarding actions of men) which alone, by means of inventions and the circulation of capital (economics) in connection with luxurious living, stimulate society into action and progress.

Francis Hutcheson [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Francis Hutcheson (1694–1746)

Francis Hutcheson (1694–1746), the teacher of Adam Smith from 1737 to 1740 [33] is considered the end of a long tradition of thought on economics as “household or family ( οἶκος ) management”, [34] [35] [36] stemming from Xenophon’s work Oeconomicus . [37] [38]

The Physiocrats and the circular flow [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Pierre Samuel du Pont de Nemours , a prominent Physiocrat , emigrated to the United States, and his son founded DuPont , the world’s second biggest chemicals company.

history of economic thought essay questions

Francois Quesnay (1694–1774)

Similarly disenchanted with regulation on trade inspired by mercantilism, a Frenchman named Vincent de Gournay (1712–1759) is reputed to have asked why it was so hard to laissez faire (“let it be”), laissez passer (“let it pass”), advocating free enterprise and free trade . He was one of the early Physiocrats , a Greek word meaning “Government of nature”, who held that agriculture was the source of wealth. As historian David B. Danbom wrote, the Physiocrats “damned cities for their artificiality and praised more natural styles of living. They celebrated farmers.” [39] Over the end of the seventeenth and beginning of the eighteenth century big advances in natural science and anatomy included discovery of blood circulation through the human body. This concept was mirrored in the physiocrats’ economic theory, with the notion of a circular flow of income throughout the economy .

François Quesnay (1694–1774) was the court physician to King Louis XV of France . He believed that trade and industry were not sources of wealth, and instead in his book Tableau économique (1758, Economic Table) argued that agricultural surpluses, by flowing through the economy in the form of rent , wages , and purchases were the real economic movers. Firstly, said Quesnay, regulation impedes the flow of income throughout all social classes and therefore economic development . Secondly, taxes on the productive classes , such as farmers , should be reduced in favour of rises for unproductive classes, such as landowners , since their luxurious way of life distorts the income flow. David Ricardo later showed that taxes on land are non-transferable to tenants in his Law of Rent .

history of economic thought essay questions

Anne Robert Jacques Turgot (1727–1781)

Jacques Turgot (1727–1781) was born in Paris to an old Norman family. His best known work, Réflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses ( Reflections on the Formation and Distribution of Wealth ) (1766) developed Quesnay’s theory that land is the only source of wealth . Turgot viewed society in terms of three classes: the productive agricultural class, the salaried artisan class ( classe stipendice ) and the landowning class ( classe disponible ). He argued that only the net product of land should be taxed and advocated the complete freedom of commerce and industry .

In August 1774 Turgot was appointed to be minister of finance, and in the space of two years he introduced many anti-mercantile and anti-feudal measures supported by the king. A statement of his guiding principles, given to the king were “no bankruptcy , no tax increases, no borrowing .” Turgot’s ultimate wish was to have a single tax on land and abolish all other indirect taxes, but measures he introduced before that were met with overwhelming opposition from landed interests. Two edicts in particular, one suppressing corvées (charges from farmers to aristocrats) and another renouncing privileges given to guilds , inflamed influential opinion. He was forced from office in 1776.

Classical (18th and 19th century) [ edit ]

Ferdinando galiani and on money [ edit ].

In 1751, Neapolitan philosopher Ferdinando Galiani published a nearly exhaustive treatise on money called Della Moneta ( On Money ), 25 years before Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations , and therefore is seen as possibly the first truly modern economic analysis. In its five sections, Della Moneta covered all modern aspects of monetary theory , including the value and origin of money, its regulation, and inflation. This text remained cited by various economists for centuries, as wide-ranging a list as Karl Marx and Austrian economist Joseph Schumpeter .

Adam Smith and The Wealth of Nations [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Adam Smith (1723–1790), father of modern political economy .

Adam Smith (1723–1790) is popularly seen as the father of modern political economy. His 1776 publication An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations happened to coincide not only with the American Revolution , shortly before the Europe-wide upheavals of the French Revolution , but also the dawn of a new industrial revolution that allowed more wealth to be created on a larger scale than ever before.

Smith was a Scottish moral philosopher, whose first book was The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759). He argued in it that people’s ethical systems develop through personal relations with other individuals, that right and wrong are sensed through others’ reactions to one’s behaviour. This gained Smith more popularity than his next work, The Wealth of Nations , which the general public initially ignored. [40] Yet Smith’s political economic magnum opus was successful in circles that mattered.

Adam Smith’s Invisible Hand [ edit ]

Smith argued for a “system of natural liberty” [42] where individual effort was the producer of social good. Smith believed even the selfish within society were kept under restraint and worked for the good of all when acting in a competitive market. Prices are often unrepresentative of the true value of goods and services. Following John Locke , Smith thought true value of things derived from the amount of labour invested in them.

Every man is rich or poor according to the degree in which he can afford to enjoy the necessaries, conveniencies, and amusements of human life. But after the division of labour has once thoroughly taken place, it is but a very small part of these with which a man’s own labour can supply him. The far greater part of them he must derive from the labour of other people, and he must be rich or poor according to the quantity of that labour which he can command, or which he can afford to purchase. The value of any commodity, therefore, to the person who possesses it, and who means not to use or consume it himself, but to exchange it for other commodities, is equal to the quantity of labour which it enables him to purchase or command. Labour, therefore, is the real measure of the exchangeable value of all commodities. The real price of every thing, what every thing really costs to the man who wants to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring it. —  [43]

When the butchers, the brewers and the bakers acted under the restraint of an open market economy, their pursuit of self-interest, thought Smith, paradoxically drives the process to correct real life prices to their just values. His classic statement on competition goes as follows.

When the quantity of any commodity which is brought to market falls short of the effectual demand, all those who are willing to pay… cannot be supplied with the quantity which they want… Some of them will be willing to give more. A competition will begin among them, and the market price will rise… When the quantity brought to market exceeds the effectual demand, it cannot be all sold to those who are willing to pay the whole value of the rent, wages and profit, which must be paid to bring it thither… The market price will sink… [44]

Limitations [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Adam Smith’s title page of The Wealth of Nations .

Smith’s vision of a free market economy, based on secure property, capital accumulation, widening markets and a division of labour contrasted with the mercantilist tendency to attempt to “regulate all evil human actions.” [42] Smith believed there were precisely three legitimate functions of government. The third function was…

…erecting and maintaining certain public works and certain public institutions, which it can never be for the interest of any individual or small number of individuals, to erect and maintain… Every system which endeavours… to draw towards a particular species of industry a greater share of the capital of the society than what would naturally go to it… retards, instead of accelerating, the progress of the society toward real wealth and greatness.

In addition to the necessity of public leadership in certain sectors Smith argued, secondly, that cartels were undesirable because of their potential to limit production and quality of goods and services. [45] Thirdly, Smith criticised government support of any kind of monopoly which always charges the highest price “which can be squeezed out of the buyers”. [46] The existence of monopoly and the potential for cartels , which would later form the core of competition law policy, could distort the benefits of free markets to the advantage of businesses at the expense of consumer sovereignty .

William Pitt the Younger [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

William Pitt the Younger (1759–1806)

William Pitt the Younger (1759–1806), Tory Prime Minister in 1783–1801 based his tax proposals on Smith’s ideas, and advocated free trade as a devout disciple of The Wealth of Nations . [47] Smith was appointed a commissioner of customs and within twenty years Smith had a following of new generation writers who were intent on building the science of political economy. [40]

Edmund Burke [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Edmund Burke (1729–1797)

Adam Smith expressed an affinity to the opinions of Irish MP Edmund Burke (1729–1797), known widely as a political philosopher:

“Burke is the only man I ever knew who thinks on economic subjects exactly as I do without any previous communication having passed between us. [48]

Burke was an established political economist himself, known for his book Thoughts and Details on Scarcity . He was widely critical of liberal politics, and condemned the French Revolution which began in 1789. In Reflections on the Revolution in France (1790) he wrote that the “age of chivalry is dead, that of sophisters, economists and calculators has succeeded, and the glory of Europe is extinguished forever.” Smith’s contemporary influences included François Quesnay and Jacques Turgot whom he met on a visit to Paris, and David Hume , his Scottish compatriot. The times produced a common need among thinkers to explain social upheavals of the Industrial revolution taking place, and in the seeming chaos without the feudal and monarchical structures of Europe, show there was order still.

Jeremy Bentham [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Jeremy Bentham (1748–1832) believed in “the greatest good for the greatest number”.

Jeremy Bentham (1748–1832) was perhaps the most radical thinker of his time, and developed the concept of utilitarianism . Bentham was an atheist , a prison reformer , animal rights activist, believer in universal suffrage , freedom of speech , free trade and health insurance at a time when few dared to argue for any of these ideas. He was schooled rigorously from an early age, finishing university and being called to the bar at 18. His first book, A Fragment on Government (1776), published anonymously, was a trenchant critique of William Blackstone ‘s Commentaries on the Laws of England . This gained wide success until it was found that the young Bentham, and not a revered Professor had penned it. In An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation (1789) Bentham set out his theory of utility . [49] [50]

Jean-Baptiste Say [ edit ]

Say’s Law , by Jean-Baptiste Say (1767–1832), which states that supply always equals demand, was rarely challenged until the 20th century.

Jean-Baptiste Say (1767–1832) was a Frenchman born in Lyon who helped popularize Adam Smith’s work in France. [51] His book A Treatise on Political Economy (1803) contained a brief passage, which later became orthodoxy in political economics until the Great Depression , now known as Say’s Law of markets. Say argued that there could never be a general deficiency of demand or a general glut of commodities in the whole economy . People produce things, to fulfill their own wants rather than those of others, therefore production is not a question of supply but an indication of producers demanding goods .

Say agreed that a part of income is saved by households, but in the long term, savings are invested. Investment and consumption are the two elements of demand , so that production is demand, therefore it is impossible for production to outrun demand, or for there to be a “general glut” of supply. Say also argued that money was neutral, because its sole role is to facilitate exchanges, therefore, people demand money only to buy commodities; “money is a veil”. [52]

David Ricardo [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

David Ricardo (1772–1823) is renowned for his law of comparative advantage .

David Ricardo (1772–1823) was born in London. By the age of 26, he had become a wealthy stock market trader, and bought himself a constituency seat in Ireland to gain a platform in the British parliament’s House of Commons . [53] Ricardo’s best known work is On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817), which contains his critique of barriers to international trade and a description of the manner in which income is distributed in the population. Ricardo made a distinction between workers, who received a wage fixed to a level at which they could survive, the landowners, who earn a rent, and capitalists, who own capital and receive a profit, a residual part of the income. [54]

If population grows, it becomes necessary to cultivate additional land, whose fertility is lower than that of already cultivated fields, because of the law of decreasing productivity. Therefore, the cost of the production of the wheat increases, as well as the price of the wheat: The rents increase also, the wages, indexed to inflation (because they must allow workers to survive) as well. Profits decrease, until the capitalists can no longer invest. The economy, Ricardo concluded, is bound to tend towards a steady state . [52]

Jean Charles Léonard de Sismondi [ edit ]

Jean Charles Léonard de Sismondi (1773–1842) The earliest author of systemic Crisis theory .

John Stuart Mill [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

John Stuart Mill (1806–1873), weaned on the philosophy of Jeremy Bentham, wrote the most authoritative economics text of his time.

John Stuart Mill (1806–1873) was the dominant figure of political economic thought of his time, as well as a Member of parliament for the seat of Westminster , and a leading political philosopher. Mill was a child prodigy, reading Ancient Greek from the age of 3, and being vigorously schooled by his father James Mill . [55] Jeremy Bentham was a close mentor and family friend, and Mill was heavily influenced by David Ricardo . Mill’s textbook, first published in 1848 and titled Principles of Political Economy was essentially a summary of the economic thought of the mid-nineteenth century. [56]

Principles of Political Economy (1848) was used as the standard text by most universities well into the beginning of the twentieth century [ citation needed ] . On the question of economic growth Mill tried to find a middle ground between Adam Smith’s view of ever-expanding opportunities for trade and technological innovation and Thomas Malthus ‘ view of the inherent limits of population. In his fourth book Mill set out a number of possible future outcomes, rather than predicting one in particular. [52]

Classical political economy [ edit ]

The classical economists were referred to as a group for the first time by Karl Marx . [57] One unifying part of their theories was the labour theory of value , contrasting to value deriving from a general equilibrium theory of supply and demand. These economists had seen the first economic and social transformation brought by the Industrial Revolution: rural depopulation , precariousness, poverty, apparition of a working class .

They wondered about population growth , because demographic transition had begun in Great Britain at that time. They also asked many fundamental questions, about the source of value, the causes of economic growth and the role of money in the economy . They supported a free- market economy , arguing it was a natural system based upon freedom and property . However, these economists were divided and did not make up a unified current of thought.

A notable current within classical economics was underconsumption theory, as advanced by the Birmingham School and Thomas Robert Malthus in the early 19th century. These argued for government action to mitigate unemployment and economic downturns, and were an intellectual predecessor of what later became Keynesian economics in the 1930s. Another notable school was Manchester capitalism , which advocated free trade , against the previous policy of mercantilism .

Karl Marx and communism [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Karl Marx (1818–1883) published a critique of classical economics based on his reinterpretation of the labor theory of value .

Marx wrote his magnum opus Das Kapital (1867) at the British Museum ‘s library in London. Karl Marx begins with the concept of commodities . Before capitalism, says Marx, production was based on slavery – in ancient Rome for example – then serfdom in the feudal societies of medieval Europe . The current mode of labor exchange [ clarification needed ] has produced an erratic and unstable situation allowing the conditions for revolution . People buy and sell their labor as people buy and sell goods and services. People themselves have become disposable commodities , as Marx wrote in The Communist Manifesto .

Marx uses the word “commodity” in an extensive metaphysical discussion of the nature of material wealth, how the objects of wealth are perceived and how they can be used. A commodity contrasts to objects of the natural world. When people mix their labor with an object it becomes a “commodity”. In the natural world there are trees, diamonds , iron ore and people. In the economic world they become chairs, rings , factories and workers. However, says Marx, commodities have a dual nature, a dual value. He distinguishes the use value of a thing from its exchange value . [58] The use value of a commodity exists only as that commodity is used or consumed. If commodities are considered absolutely isolated from their useful qualities the common property is human labor in the abstract . Marx attempted to support his theory by linking his ideas of “ surplus value ” and “ socially necessary labor time ” with the classical labor theory of value and theories of rent . Marx theorized that people over-value commodities such as glimmering diamonds. [59] Marx applied the use/exchange distinction to labor and claimed that employers pay their workers less in “exchange value” than the workers produce in “use value”. The difference, in Marx’s terminology, is “ surplus value “. [60] Therefore, says Marx, capitalism is a system of exploitation .

Marx believed that a reserve army of the unemployed would grow and grow, fueling a downward pressure on wages as desperate people accepted work for less. But this would produce a deficit of demand as the people’s power to purchase products lagged. A glut of unsold products would result, production would be cut back, and profits decline until capital accumulation halted in an economic depression . When the glut cleared, the economy would again start to boom before the next cyclical bust begins. With every boom and bust , with every capitalist crisis, thought Marx, tension and conflict between the increasingly polarized classes of capitalists and workers would heighten. Ultimately, led by the Communist party , Marx envisaged a revolution and the creation of a classless society.

Henry George and Georgism [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

In 1879, Henry George published an explosively popular treatise on why poverty accompanies progress and boom follows bust.

Henry George (1839-1897) is popularly recognized as the intellectual inspiration for the economic philosophy now known as Georgism . George is said to be the last classical economist. During his life, George was one of the three most famous Americans, along with Henry Ford and Thomas Edison . George’s first book, Progress and Poverty , was one of the most widely printed books in English, selling between 3 and 6 million copies by the early 1900s. Progress and Poverty sparked a worldwide reform movement and is sometimes marked as the beginning of the Progressive Era . Georgism declined in the second half of the 20th Century as the Marxist and Austrian and Keynesian neoclassical schools gained popularity. However, there are still active Georgist organizations and land reform movements around the world. George’s ideas have been incorporated into the philosophies of socialism , libertarianism , and ecological economics . Paul Samuelson listed Henry George as one of only six “American saints” in classical economics. [61]

The London School of Economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Beatrice Webb (1858–1943)

history of economic thought essay questions

Sidney Webb (1859–1947)

history of economic thought essay questions

George Bernard Shaw (1856–1950)

history of economic thought essay questions

Sir Roy Allen (1906–1983)

In 1895 the London School of Economics (LSE) was founded by Fabian Society members Sidney Webb (1859–1947), Beatrice Webb (1858–1943), and George Bernard Shaw (1856–1950), joining the University of London in 1900.

In the 1930s LSE member Sir Roy G.D. Allen (1906–1983) popularized the use of mathematics in economics.

Neoclassical (19th and early 20th century) [ edit ]

Neoclassical economics developed in the 1870s. There were three main independent schools. The Cambridge School was founded with the 1871 publication of Jevons’ Theory of Political Economy , developing theories of partial equilibrium and focusing on market failures. Its main representatives were Stanley Jevons , Alfred Marshall , and Arthur Pigou . The Austrian School of Economics was made up of Austrian economists Carl Menger , Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk , and Friedrich von Wieser , who developed the theory of capital and tried to explain economic crises. It was founded with the 1871 publication of Menger’s Principles of Economics . The Lausanne School , led by Léon Walras and Vilfredo Pareto , developed the theories of general equilibrium and Pareto efficiency . It was founded with the 1874 publication of Walras’ Elements of Pure Economics .

Anglo-American neoclassical [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

John Bates Clark (1847–1938)

American economist John Bates Clark (1847–1938) promoted the marginalist revolution , publishing The Distribution of Wealth (1899), which proposed Clark’s Law of Capitalism: “Given competition and homogeneous factors of production labor and capital, the repartition of the social product will be according to the productivity of the last physical input of units of labor and capital”, also expressed as “What a social class gets is, under natural law, what it contributes to the general output of industry.” In 1947 the John Bates Clark Medal was established in his honor. [50]

William Stanley Jevons [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

William Stanley Jevons (1835–1882) helped popularize marginal utility theory.

In 1871 Menger’s English counterpart Stanley Jevons (1835–1882) independently published Theory of Political Economy (1871), stating that at the margin the satisfaction of goods and services decreases. An example of the Theory of Diminishing Marginal Utility is that for every orange one eats, one gets less pleasure until one stops eating oranges completely. [50]

Alfred Marshall [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Alfred Marshall (1842–1924) wrote the main alternative textbook to John Stuart Mill of the day, Principles of Economics (1890)

Alfred Marshall (1842–1924) is also credited with an attempt to put economics on a more mathematical footing. The first professor of economics at the University of Cambridge , his 1890 work Principles of Economics [62] abandoned the term “ political economy ” for his favorite “ economics “. He viewed math as a way to simplify economic reasoning, although he had reservations as revealed in a letter to his student Arthur Cecil Pigou : [50] [63]

(1) Use mathematics as shorthand language, rather than as an engine of inquiry. (2) Keep to them till you have done. (3) Translate into English. (4) Then illustrate by examples that are important in real life. (5) Burn the mathematics. (6) If you can’t succeed in 4, burn 3. This I do often.

New institutional schools [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Harold Demsetz (1930–)

In 1972 American economists Harold Demsetz (1930–) and Armen Alchian (1914–2013) published Production, Information Costs and Economic Organization , founding New Institutional Economics , an updating of the works of Ronald Coase (1910–2013) with mainstream economics. [50]

Continental neoclassical [ edit ]

Léon walras [ edit ].

history of economic thought essay questions

Léon Walras (1834–1910)

In 1874 again working independently, French economist Léon Walras (1834–1910) generalized marginal theory across the economy in Elements of Pure Economics : Small changes in people’s preferences, for instance shifting from beef to mushrooms, would lead to a mushroom price rise, and beef price fall; this stimulates producers to shift production, increasing mushrooming investment, which would increase market supply and a new price equilibrium between the products, e.g. lowering the price of mushrooms to a level between the two first levels. For many products across the economy the same would happen if one assumes markets are competitive, people choose on the basis of self-interest, and there’s no cost for shifting production. [50]

The Austrian school of economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (1851–1914)

history of economic thought essay questions

Friedrich von Wieser (1851–1926)

While economics at the end of the nineteenth century and the beginning of the twentieth was dominated increasingly by mathematical analysis, the followers of Carl Menger (1840–1921) and his disciples Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (1851–1914) and Friedrich von Wieser (1851–1926) (coiner of the term “marginal utility”) followed a different route, advocating the use of deductive logic instead. This group became known as the Austrian School of Economics , reflecting the Austrian origin of many of the early adherents. Thorstein Veblen in The Preconceptions of Economic Science (1900) contrasted neoclassical marginalists in the tradition of Alfred Marshall with the philosophies of the Austrian School. [64] [65]

Carl Menger [ edit ]

In 1871 Austrian School economist Carl Menger (1840–1921) restated the basic principles of marginal utility in Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre [66] ( Principles of Economics ): Consumers act rationally by seeking to maximize satisfaction of all their preferences; people allocate their spending so that the last unit of a commodity bought creates no more satisfaction than a last unit bought of something else. [50]

Francis Ysidro Edgeworth [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (1845–1926)

In 1881 Irish economist Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (1845–1926) published Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences , which introduced indifference curves and the generalized utility function, along with Edgeworth’s Limit Theorem , extending the Bertrand Model to handle capacity constraints, and proposing Edgeworth’s Paradox for when there is no limit to what the firms can sell. [50]

Friedrich Hayek [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Friedrich Hayek (1899–1992)

In echoes of Smith’s “system of natural liberty”, Hayek argued that the market is a “spontaneous order” and actively disparaged the concept of “ social justice “. [67] Ludwig von Mises ‘s outspoken criticisms of socialism had a large influence on the economic thinking of Austrian School economist Friedrich Hayek (1899–1992), who, while initially sympathetic, became one of the leading academic critics of collectivism in the 20th century. [68] Hayek believed that all forms of collectivism (even those theoretically based on voluntary cooperation) could only be maintained by a central authority. But he argued that centralizing economic decision-making would lead not only to infringements of liberty but also to depressed standards of living because centralized experts could not gather and assess the knowledge required to allocate scarce resources efficiently or productively. In his book, The Road to Serfdom (1944) and in subsequent works, Hayek claimed that socialism required central economic planning and that such planning in turn would lead towards totalitarianism . Hayek attributed the birth of civilization to private property in his book The Fatal Conceit (1988). According to him, price signals are the only means of enabling each economic decision maker to communicate tacit knowledge or dispersed knowledge to each other, to solve the economic calculation problem . Along with his Socialist Swedish contemporary and opponent Gunnar Myrdal (1898–1987), Hayek was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1974. [69]

Alternative schools (19th century) [ edit ]

Business cycle theory [ edit ].

history of economic thought essay questions

Sir William Herschel (1738–1822)

Clément Juglar (1819–1905)

history of economic thought essay questions

Nikolai Kondratiev (1892–1938)

In the early 19th century German-born English astronomer Sir William Herschel (1738–1822) noted a connection between 11-year sunspot cycles and wheat prices. In 1860 French economist Clément Juglar (1819–1905) posited business cycles seven to eleven years long. In 1925 the Soviet economist Nikolai Kondratiev (1892–1938) proposed the existence of Kondratiev waves in Western capitalist economies fifty to sixty years long.

German historical school of economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Wilhelm Roscher (1817–1894)

In the mid-1840s German economist Wilhelm Roscher (1817–1894) founded the German historical school of economics , which promoted the cyclical theory of nations—economies passing through youth, manhood, and senility—and spread through academia in Britain and the U.S., dominating it for the rest of the 19th century. [50]

Thorstein Veblen and the American Way [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Thorstein Veblen (1857–1929)

Thorstein Veblen (1857–1929), who came from rural midwestern America and worked at the University of Chicago is one of the best-known early critics of the “American Way”. In The Theory of the Leisure Class (1899) he scorned materialistic culture and wealthy people who conspicuously consumed their riches as a way of demonstrating success. In The Theory of Business Enterprise (1904) Veblen distinguished production for people to use things and production for pure profit, arguing that the former is often hindered because businesses pursue the latter. Output and technological advance are restricted by business practices and the creation of monopolies. Businesses protect their existing capital investments and employ excessive credit, leading to depressions and increasing military expenditure and war through business control of political power. These two books, focusing on criticism of consumerism and profiteering did not advocate change. However, in 1918 he moved to New York to begin work as an editor of a magazine called The Dial , and then in 1919, along with Charles A. Beard , James Harvey Robinson , and John Dewey he helped found the New School for Social Research (known today as The New School ). He was also part of the Technical Alliance , [70] created in 1919 by Howard Scott . From 1919 through 1926 Veblen continued to write and to be involved in various activities at The New School. During this period he wrote The Engineers and the Price System (1921). [50] [71]

World wars, revolution and great depression (early to mid 20th century) [ edit ]

At the outbreak of World War I (1914 –1918), Alfred Marshall was still working on his last revisions of his Principles of Economics . The 20th century’s initial climate of optimism was soon violently dismembered in the trenches of the Western Front. During the war, production in Britain, Germany, and France was switched to the military. In 1917 Russia crumbled into revolution led by Vladimir Lenin and who promoted Marxist theory and collectivized the means of production. Also in 1917 the United States of America entered the war Allies (France and Britain) , with President Woodrow Wilson claiming to be “making the world safe for democracy”, devising a peace plan of Fourteen Points . In 1918 Germany launched a spring offensive which failed, and as the allies counterattacked and more millions were slaughtered, Germany slid into the German Revolution , its interim government suing for peace on the basis of Wilson’s Fourteen Points. After the war, Europe lay in ruins, financially, physically, psychologically, and its future was dependent on the dictates of the Versailles Conference in 1919.

After World War I, Europe and the Soviet Union lay in ruins, and the British Empire was nearing its end, leaving the United States as the preeminent global economic power. Before World War II, American economists had played a minor role. During this time institutional economists had been largely critical of the “American Way” of life, especially the conspicuous consumption of the Roaring Twenties before the Wall Street Crash of 1929 . The most important development in economic thought during the Great Depression was the Keynesian revolution , including the publication in 1936 of The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money by John Maynard Keynes . (See the discussion of Keynesianism below.) Subsequently, a more orthodox body of thought took root, reacting against the lucid debating style of Keynes, and remathematizing the profession. The orthodox center was also challenged by a more radical group of scholars based at the University of Chicago, who advocated “liberty” and “freedom”, looking back to 19th century-style non-interventionist governments. [ citation needed ]

Econometrics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Ragnar Frisch (1895–1973)

history of economic thought essay questions

Jan Tinbergen (1903–1994)

history of economic thought essay questions

Clive Granger (1934–2009)

history of economic thought essay questions

Trygve Haavelmo (1911–1999)

In the 1930s Norwegian economist Ragnar Frisch (1895–1973) and Dutch economist Jan Tinbergen (1903–1994) pioneered Econometrics , receiving the first-ever Nobel Prize in Economics in 1969. In 1936 Russian-American economist Wassily Leontief (1905–1999) proposed the Input-Output Model of economics, which uses linear algebra and is ideally suited to computers, receiving the 1973 Nobel Economics Prize. After World War II, Lawrence Klein (1920–) pioneered the use of computers in econometric modeling, receiving the 1980 Nobel Economics Prize. In 1963–1964 as John Tukey of Princeton University was developing the revolutionary Fast Fourier Transform , which greatly speed up the calculation of Fourier Transforms, his British assistant Sir Clive Granger (1934–2009) pioneered the use of Fourier Transforms in economics, receiving the 2003 Nobel Economics Prize. Ragnar Frisch’s assistant Trygve Haavelmo (1911–1999) received the 1989 Nobel Economics Prize for clarifying the probability foundations of econometrics and for analysis of simultaneous economic structures.

Means and corporate governance [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Adolf Augustus Berle, Jr. (1895–1971) with Gardiner Means was a foundational figure of modern corporate governance .

The Great Depression was a time of significant upheaval in the world economy. One of the most original contributions to understanding what went wrong came from Harvard University lawyer Adolf Berle (1895–1971), who like John Maynard Keynes had resigned from his diplomatic job at the Paris Peace Conference, 1919 and was deeply disillusioned by the Versailles Treaty . In his book with American economist Gardiner C. Means (1896–1988) The Modern Corporation and Private Property (1932) he detailed the evolution in the contemporary economy of big business, and argued that those who controlled big firms should be better held to account. Directors of companies are held to account to the shareholders of companies, or not, by the rules found in company law statutes. This might include rights to elect and fire the management, require for regular general meetings, accounting standards, and so on. In 1930s America the typical company laws (e.g. in Delaware ) did not clearly mandate such rights. Berle argued that the unaccountable directors of companies were therefore apt to funnel the fruits of enterprise profits into their own pockets, as well as manage in their own interests. The ability to do this was supported by the fact that the majority of shareholders in big public companies were single individuals, with scant means of communication, in short, divided and conquered. Berle served in President Franklin Delano Roosevelt ‘s administration through the Great Depression as a key member of his Brain Trust , developing many New Deal policies.

In 1967 Berle and Means issued a revised edition of their work, in which the preface added a new dimension. It was not only the separation of controllers of companies from the owners as shareholders at stake. They posed the question of what the corporate structure was really meant to achieve:

“Stockholders toil not, neither do they spin, to earn [dividends and share price increases]. They are beneficiaries by position only. Justification for their inheritance… can be founded only upon social grounds… that justification turns on the distribution as well as the existence of wealth. Its force exists only in direct ratio to the number of individuals who hold such wealth. Justification for the stockholder’s existence thus depends on increasing distribution within the American population. Ideally the stockholder’s position will be impregnable only when every American family has its fragment of that position and of the wealth by which the opportunity to develop individuality becomes fully actualized.” [72]

Industrial organization economics [ edit ]

In 1933 American economist Edward Chamberlin (1899–1967) published The Theory of Monopolistic Competition . The same year British economist Joan Robinson (1903–1983) published The Economics of Imperfect Competition . Together they founded Industrial Organization Economics . Chamberlin also founded Experimental Economics .

Linear programming [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Leonid Kantorovich (1912–1986)

In 1939 Russian economist Leonid Kantorovich (1912–1986) developed Linear Programming for the optimal allocation of resources, receiving the 1975 Nobel Economics Prize.

Ecology and energy [ edit ]

By the twentieth century, the industrial revolution had led to an exponential increase in the human consumption of resources. The increase in health, wealth and population was perceived as a simple path of progress. However, in the 1930s economists began developing models of non-renewable resource management (see Hotelling’s rule ) and the sustainability of welfare in an economy that uses non-renewable resources.

Concerns about the environmental and social impacts of industry had been expressed by some Enlightenment political economists and in the Romantic movement of the 1800s. Overpopulation had been discussed in an essay by Thomas Malthus (see Malthusian catastrophe ), while John Stuart Mill foresaw the desirability of a stationary state economy , thus anticipating concerns of the modern discipline of ecological economics . [73] [74] [75] [76] [77]

Ecological economics [ edit ]

Ecological economics was founded in the works of Kenneth E. Boulding , Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen , Herman Daly and others. The disciplinary field of ecological economics also bears some similarity to the topic of green economics. [78]

According to ecological economist Malte Faber, ecological economics is defined by its focus on nature, justice, and time. Issues of intergenerational equity , irreversibility of human impact on the environment , uncertainty of long-term outcomes, thermodynamics limits to growth, and sustainable development guide ecological economic analysis and valuation. [79]

Energy accounting [ edit ]

Energy accounting was proposed in the early 1930s as a scientific alternative to a price system , or money method of regulating society. [80] [81] Joseph Tainter [82] suggests that a diminishing ratio of energy returned on energy invested is a chief cause of the collapse of complex societies. Falling EROEI due to depletion of non-renewable resources also poses a difficult challenge for industrial economies. Sustainability becomes an issue as survival is threatened due to climate change.

Institutional economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

John R. Commons (1862–1945)

In 1919 Yale economist Walton H. Hamilton coined the term “ Institutional economics “. In 1934 John R. Commons (1862–1945), another economist from midwestern America published Institutional Economics (1934), based on the concept that the economy is a web of relationships between people with diverging interests, including monopolies, large corporations, labor disputes, and fluctuating business cycles. They do however have an interest in resolving these disputes. Government, thought Commons, ought to be the mediator between the conflicting groups. Commons himself devoted much of his time to advisory and mediation work on government boards and industrial commissions.

Arthur Cecil Pigou [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Arthur Cecil Pigou (1877–1959)

In 1920 Alfred Marshall’s student Arthur Cecil Pigou (1877–1959) published Wealth and Welfare , which insisted on the possibility of market failures , claiming that markets are inefficient in the case of economic externalities , and the state must interfere to prevent them. However, Pigou retained free market beliefs, and in 1933, in the face of the economic crisis, he explained in The Theory of Unemployment that the excessive intervention of the state in the labor market was the real cause of massive unemployment because the governments had established a minimal wage, which prevented wages from adjusting automatically. This was to be the focus of attack from Keynes. In 1943 Pigou published the paper The Classical Stationary State , which popularized the Pigou (Real Balance) Effect , the stimulation of output and employment during deflation by increasing consumption due to a rise in wealth

Market socialism [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Fred M. Taylor (1855–1932)

history of economic thought essay questions

Oskar R. Lange (1904–1965)

history of economic thought essay questions

Abba Lerner (1903–1982)

In response to the Economic Calculation Problem proposed by the Austrian School of Economics that disputes the efficiency of a state-run economy, the theory of Market Socialism was developed in the late 1920s and 1930s by economists Fred M. Taylor (1855–1932), Oskar R. Lange (1904–1965), Abba Lerner (1903–1982) et al., combining Marxian economics with neoclassical economics after dumping the labor theory of value. In 1938 Abram Bergson (1914–2003) defined the Social Welfare Function .

The Stockholm school of economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Eli Heckscher (1879–1952)

history of economic thought essay questions

Bertil Ohlin (1899–1977)

history of economic thought essay questions

Gunnar Myrdal (1898–1987)

history of economic thought essay questions

Knut Wicksell (1851–1926)

In the 1930s the Stockholm School of Economics was founded by Eli Heckscher (1879–1952), Bertil Ohlin (1899–1977), Gunnar Myrdal (1898–1987) et al. based on the works of John Maynard Keynes and Knut Wicksell (1851–1926), advising the founders of the Swedish Socialist welfare state.

In 1933 Ohlin and Heckscher proposed the Heckscher-Ohlin Model of International Trade , which claims that countries will export products that use their abundant and cheap factors of production and import products that use their scarce factors of production. In 1977 Ohlin was awarded a share of the Nobel Economics Prize.

In 1957 Myrdal published his theory of Circular Cumulative Causation , in which a change in one institution ripples through others. In 1974 he received a share of the Nobel Economics Prize.

French Regulation school [ edit ]

This school includes economists like Michel Aglietta (1938), André Orléan (1950), Robert Boyer  [ fr ] (1943), Benjamin Coriat (1948) and Alain Lipietz (1947). It is one of the two heterodox schools in France, the other being l’école des conventions . Their interests revolves around accounting for the regime of regulation of specific historic stage of capitalsim. They have mainly analysed the fordist mode of regulation, who corresponds to the after war period. Production as organised scientificically and products weren’t diversified. This corresponds with a homogenous consumption of goods. The economy was production lead, where firms first produce the optimal amount of a type of good in the cheapest manner possible, destined to me mass comsummed. Their inquiry consists of explaining how a stable mode of regulation can emerge in a capilist economy, which inherently contains crises. Whereas orthodox economists tend to explain the causes of crises and disequilibriums in a supposibly self-regulating economy.

Alternative schools (20th century) [ edit ]

The american economic association [ edit ].

history of economic thought essay questions

Richard T. Ely (1854–1943)

In 1885 the American Economic Association (AEA) was founded by Richard T. Ely (1854–1943) et al., publishing the American Economic Review starting in 1911. In 1918 Ely published Private Colonization of Land , founding Lambda Alpha International in 1930 to promote Land Economics . [50]

Keynesianism (20th century) [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946) (right) with his American counterpart Harry White at the Bretton Woods conference .

John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946) was born in Cambridge, educated at Eton , and supervised by both A. C. Pigou and Alfred Marshall at Cambridge University . He began his career as a lecturer before working for the British government during the Great War, rising to be the British government’s financial representative at the Versailles Conference , where he profoundly disagreed with the decisions made. His observations were laid out in his book The Economic Consequences of the Peace [83] (1919), where he documented his outrage at the collapse of American adherence to the Fourteen Points [84] and the mood of vindictiveness that prevailed towards Germany., [85] and he resigned from the conference, using extensive economic data provided by the conference records to argue that if the victors forced war reparations to be paid by the defeated Central Powers , then a world financial crisis would ensue, leading to a second world war. [86] Keynes finished his treatise by advocating, first, a reduction in reparation payments by Germany to a realistically manageable level, increased intra-governmental management of continental coal production and a free trade union through the League of Nations ; [87] second, an arrangement to set off debt repayments between the Allied countries; [88] third, complete reform of international currency exchange and an international loan fund; [89] and fourth, a reconciliation of trade relations with Russia and Eastern Europe. [90]

The book was an enormous success, and though it was criticized for false predictions by a number of people, [91] without the changes he advocated, Keynes’s dark forecasts matched the world’s experience through the Great Depression which began in 1929, and the descent into World War II in 1939. World War I had been touted as the “war to end all wars”, and the absolute failure of the peace settlement generated an even greater determination to not repeat the same mistakes. With the defeat of Fascism , the Bretton Woods Conference was held in July 1944 to establish a new economic order, in which Keynes was again to play a leading role. [92]

The General Theory [ edit ]

During the Great Depression, Keynes published his most important work, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936). The Great Depression had been sparked by the Wall Street Crash of 1929 , leading to massive rises in unemployment in the United States, leading to debts being recalled from European borrowers, and an economic domino effect across the world. Orthodox economics called for a tightening of spending, until business confidence and profit levels could be restored. Keynes by contrast, had argued in A Tract on Monetary Reform (1923) (which argues for a stable currency) that a variety of factors determined economic activity, and that it was not enough to wait for the long run market equilibrium to restore itself. As Keynes famously remarked:

“…this long run is a misleading guide to current affairs. In the long run we are all dead. Economists set themselves too easy, too useless a task if in tempestuous seasons they can only tell us that when the storm is long past the ocean is flat again.” [93]

On top of the supply of money , Keynes identified the propensity to consume , inducement to invest, marginal efficiency of capital, liquidity preference, and multiplier effect as variables which determine the level of the economy’s output, employment, and price levels. Much of this esoteric terminology was invented by Keynes especially for his General Theory . Keynes argued that if savings were being withheld from investment in financial markets , total spending falls, leading to reduced incomes and unemployment, which reduces savings again. This continues until the desire to save becomes equal to the desire to invest, which means a new “equilibrium” is reached and the spending decline halts. This new “equilibrium” is a depression, where people are investing less, have less to save and less to spend.

Keynes argued that employment depends on total spending, which is composed of consumer spending and business investment in the private sector . Consumers only spend “passively”, or according to their income fluctuations. Businesses, on the other hand, are induced to invest by the expected rate of return on new investments (the benefit) and the rate of interest paid (the cost). So, said Keynes, if business expectations remained the same, and government reduces interest rates (the costs of borrowing), investment would increase, and would have a multiplied effect on total spending. Interest rates , in turn, depend on the quantity of money and the desire to hold money in bank accounts (as opposed to investing). If not enough money is available to match how much people want to hold, interest rates rise until enough people are put off. So if the quantity of money were increased, while the desire to hold money remained stable, interest rates would fall, leading to increased investment, output and employment. For both these reasons, Keynes therefore advocated low interest rates and easy credit, to combat unemployment.

But Keynes believed in the 1930s, conditions necessitated public sector action. Deficit spending , said Keynes, would kick-start economic activity. This he had advocated in an open letter to U.S. President Franklin D. Roosevelt in the New York Times (1933). The New Deal programme in the U.S. had been well underway by the publication of the General Theory . It provided conceptual reinforcement for policies already pursued. Keynes also believed in a more egalitarian distribution of income, and taxation on unearned income arguing that high rates of savings (to which richer folk are prone) are not desirable in a developed economy. Keynes therefore advocated both monetary management and an active fiscal policy.

The Cambridge Circus [ edit ]

During World War II Keynes acted as adviser to HM Treasury again, negotiating major loans from the U.S., helping formulate the plans for the International Monetary Fund , the World Bank , and the International Trade Organisation [94] at the 1944 Bretton Woods Conference , a package designed to stabilize world economy fluctuations that had occurred in the 1920s and create a level trading field across the globe. Keynes died little more than a year later, but his ideas had already shaped a new global economic order, and all Western governments followed the Keynesian economics program of deficit spending to avert crises and maintain full employment.

history of economic thought essay questions

Joan Robinson (1903–1983)

One of Keynes’s pupils at Cambridge was Joan Robinson (1903–1983), a member of Keynes’s Cambridge Circus , who contributed to the notion that competition is seldom perfect in a market, an indictment of the theory of markets setting prices. In The Production Function and the Theory of Capital (1953) Robinson tackled what she saw to be some of the circularity in orthodox economics. Neoclassicists assert that a competitive market forces producers to minimize the costs of production. Robinson said that costs of production are merely the prices of inputs, like capital . Capital goods get their value from the final products. And if the price of the final products determines the price of capital, then it is, argued Robinson, utterly circular to say that the price of capital determines the price of the final products. Goods cannot be priced until the costs of inputs are determined. This would not matter if everything in the economy happened instantaneously, but in the real world, price setting takes time – goods are priced before they are sold. Since capital cannot be adequately valued in independently measurable units, how can one show that capital earns a return equal to the contribution to production?

Alfred Eichner (1937–1988) was an American post-Keynesian economist who challenged the neoclassical price mechanism and asserted that prices are not set through supply and demand but rather through mark-up pricing. Eichner is one of the founders of the post-Keynesian school of economics and was a professor at Rutgers University at the time of his death. Eichner’s writings and advocacy of thought, differed with the theories of John Maynard Keynes, who was an advocate of government intervention in the free market and proponent of public spending to increase employment. Eichner argued that investment was the key to economic expansion. He was considered an advocate of the concept that government incomes policy should prevent inflationary wage and price settlements in connection to the customary fiscal and monetary means of regulating the economy.

Richard Kahn (1905–1989) was a member of the Cambridge Circus who in 1931 proposed the Multiplier .

history of economic thought essay questions

Piero Sraffa (1898–1983)

Piero Sraffa (1898–1983) came to England from Fascist Italy in the 1920s, and became a member of the Cambridge Circus. In 1960 he published a small book called Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities , which explained how technological relationships are the basis for production of goods and services. Prices result from wage-profit tradeoffs, collective bargaining, labour and management conflict and the intervention of government planning. Like Robinson, Sraffa was showing how the major force for price setting in the economy was not necessarily market adjustments.

John Hicks (1904–1989) of England was a Keynesian who in 1937 proposed the Investment Saving – Liquidity Preference Money Supply Model , which treats the intersection of the IS and LM curves as the general equilibrium in both markets.

New Keynesian macroeconomics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

In 1977 Edmund Phelps (1933–) (who was awarded the 2006 Nobel Economics Prize) and John B. Taylor (1946–) published a paper proving that staggered setting of wages and prices gives monetary policy a role in stabilizing economic fluctuations if the wages/prices are sticky , even when all workers and firms have rational expectations, which caused Keynesian economics to make a comeback among mainstream economists with New Keynesian Macroeconomics . Its central theme is the provision of a microeconomic foundation for Keynesian macroeconomics, obtained by identifying minimal deviations from the standard microeconomic assumptions which yield Keynesian macroeconomic conclusions, such as the possibility of significant welfare benefits from macroeconomic stabilization. [95]

In 1985 George Akerlof (1940–) and Janet Yellen (1946–) published menu costs arguments showing that, under imperfect competition, small deviations from rationality generate significant (in welfare terms) price stickiness . [96]

In 1987 British economist Huw Dixon (1958–) published A simple model of imperfect competition with Walrasian features , [97] the first work to demonstrate in a simple general equilibrium model that the fiscal multiplier could be increasing with the degree of imperfect competition in the output market, helping develop New Keynesian economics . The reason for this is that imperfect competition in the output market tends to reduce the real wage , leading to the household substituting away from consumption towards leisure . When government spending is increased, the corresponding increase in lump-sum taxation causes both leisure and consumption to decrease (assuming that they are both a normal good). The greater the degree of imperfect competition in the output market, the lower the real wage and hence the more the reduction falls on leisure (i.e. households work more) and less on consumption. Hence the fiscal multiplier is less than one, but increasing in the degree of imperfect competition in the output market. [98]

In 1997 American economist Michael Woodford (1955–) and Argentine economist Julio Rotemberg (1953–) published the first paper describing a microfounded DSGE New Keynesian macroeconomic model.

Sidney Weintraub, Paul Davidson and Post-Keynesian economics [ edit ]

In 1975 American economists Sidney Weintraub (1914–1983) and Henry Wallich (1914–1988) published A Tax-Based Incomes Policy , promoting Tax-Based Incomes Policy (TIP) , using the income tax mechanism to implement an anti-inflationary incomes policy. In 1978 Weintraub and American economist Paul Davidson (1930–) founded the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics . This opened the door to many younger economists such as E. Ray Canterbery (1935–). Always Post Keynesian in his style and approach, Canterbery went on to make contributions outside traditional Post Keynesianism. His friend, John Kenneth Galbraith, was a long-time influence.

The credit theory of money [ edit ]

In 1913 English economist-diplomat Alfred Mitchell-Innes (1864–1950) published What is Money? , which was reviewed favorably by John Maynard Keynes , followed in 1914 by The Credit Theory of Money , advocating the Credit Theory of Money , which economist L. Randall Wray called “The best pair of articles on the nature of money written in the twentieth century.” [99]

The Chicago school of economics (20th century) [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Milton Friedman (1912–2006)

history of economic thought essay questions

Jacob Mincer (1922–2006)

history of economic thought essay questions

Gary Becker (1930–2014)

history of economic thought essay questions

Richard Posner (1939–)

The government-interventionist monetary and fiscal policies that the postwar Keynesian economists recommended came under attack by a group of theorists working at the University of Chicago , which came in the 1950s to be known as the Chicago School of Economics . Before World War II, the Old Chicago School of strong Keynesians was founded by Frank Knight (1885–1972), Jacob Viner (1892–1970), and Henry Calvert Simons (1899–1946). The second generation was known for a more conservative line of thought, reasserting a libertarian view of market activity that people are best left to themselves to be free to choose how to conduct their own affairs. [50]

Ronald Coase (1910–2013) of the Chicago School of Economics was the most prominent economic analyst of law, and the 1991 Nobel Prize in Economics winner. His first major article The Nature of the Firm (1937) argued that the reason for the existence of firms ( companies , partnerships, etc.) is the existence of transaction costs . Homo economicus trades through bilateral contracts on open markets until the costs of transactions make the use of corporations to produce things more cost-effective. His second major article The Problem of Social Cost (1960) argued that if we lived in a world without transaction costs, people would bargain with one another to create the same allocation of resources, regardless of the way a court might rule in property disputes. Coase used the example of an old legal case about nuisance named Sturges v Bridgman , where a noisy sweets maker and a quiet doctor were neighbors and went to court to see who should have to move. [100] Coase said that regardless of whether the judge ruled that the sweets maker had to stop using his machinery, or that the doctor had to put up with it, they could strike a mutually beneficial bargain about who moves house that reaches the same outcome of resource distribution. Only the existence of transaction costs may prevent this. [101] So the law ought to preempt what would happen, and be guided by the most efficient solution. The idea is that law and regulation are not as important or effective at helping people as lawyers and government planners believe. [102] Coase and others like him wanted a change of approach, to put the burden of proof for positive effects on a government that was intervening in the market, by analyzing the costs of action. [103]

In the 1960s Gary Becker (1930–2014) and Jacob Mincer (1922–2006) of the Chicago School of Economics founded New Home Economics , which spawned Family Economics .

In 1973 Coase disciple Richard Posner (1939–) published Economic Analysis of Law , which became a standard textbook, causing him to become the most cited legal scholar of the 20th century. In 1981 he published The Economics of Justice , which claimed that judges have been interpreting common law as it they were trying to maximize economic welfare.

Milton Friedman (1912–2006) of the Chicago School of Economics is one of the most influential economists of the late 20th, century, receiving the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1976. He is known for A Monetary History of the United States (1963), in which he argued that the Great Depression was caused by the policies of the Federal Reserve . Friedman argues that laissez-faire government policy is more desirable than government intervention in the economy. Governments should aim for a neutral monetary policy oriented toward long-run economic growth , by gradual expansion of the money supply. He advocates the quantity theory of money , that general prices are determined by money. Therefore, active monetary (e.g. easy credit) or fiscal (e.g. tax and spend) policy can have unintended negative effects. In Capitalism and Freedom (1962), Friedman wrote:

“There is likely to be a lag between the need for action and government recognition of the need; a further lag between recognition of the need for action and the taking of action; and a still further lag between the action and its effects.” [104]

Friedman was also known for his work on the consumption function, the Permanent Income Hypothesis (1957), which Friedman referred to as his best scientific work. [105] This work contended that rational consumers would spend a proportional amount of what they perceived to be their permanent income. Windfall gains would mostly be saved. Tax reductions likewise, as rational consumers would predict that taxes would have to rise later to balance public finances. Other important contributions include his critique of the Phillips Curve , and the concept of the natural rate of unemployment (1968). [50]

New classical macroeconomics and synthesis [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Prescott (1940–) , Sargent (1943–) , Kydland (1948–)

In the early 1970s American Chicago School economist Robert E. Lucas, Jr. (1937–) founded New Classical Macroeconomics based on Milton Friedman ‘s monetarist critique of Keynesian macroeconomics, and the idea of rational expectations , [106] first proposed in 1961 by John F. Muth , opposing the idea that government intervention can or should stabilize the economy. [107] The Policy-Ineffectiveness Proposition (1975) [108] of Thomas J. Sargent (1943–) and Neil Wallace (1939–), which seemed to refute a basic assumption of Keynesian economics was also adopted. The Lucas aggregate supply function states that economic output is a function of money or price “surprise.” Lucas was awarded the 1995 Nobel Economics Prize.

Lucas’ model was superseded as the standard model of New Classical Macroeconomics by the Real Business Cycle Theory , proposed in 1982 by Finn Kydland (1943–) and Edward C. Prescott (1940–), which seeks to explain observed fluctuations in output and employment in terms of real variables such as changes in technology and tastes. Assuming competitive markets, real business cycle theory implies that cyclical fluctuations are optimal responses to variability in technology and tastes, and that macroeconomic stabilization policies must reduce welfare. [109]

In 1982 Kydland and Prescott also founded the theory of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE), large systems of microeconomic equations combined into models of the general economy, which became central to the New Neoclassical Synthesis , incorporating theoretical elements such as sticky prices from New Keynesian Macroeconomics. They shared the 2004 Nobel Economics Prize. [50]

Efficient market hypothesis [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Eugene Fama (1939–)

In 1965 Chicago School economist Eugene Fama (1939–) published The Behavior of Stock Market Prices , which found that stock market prices follow a random walk, proposing the Efficient Market Hypothesis , that randomness is characteristic of a perfectly functioning financial market. The same year Paul Samuelson published a paper concluding the same thing with a mathematical proof, sharing the credit. Earlier in 1948 Holbrook Working (1895–1985) published a paper saying the same thing, but not in a mathematical form. In 1970 Fama published Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work , proposing that efficient markets can be strong, semi-strong, or weak, and also proposing the Joint Hypothesis Problem , that the idea of market efficiency can’t be rejected without also rejecting the market mechanism.

Games, evolution and growth (20th century) [ edit ]

John von Neumann (1903–1957)

history of economic thought essay questions

John Forbes Nash Jr. (1928-2015)

history of economic thought essay questions

Joseph Alois Schumpeter (1883–1950)

history of economic thought essay questions

Robert Solow (1924–)

In 1898 Thorstein Veblen published Why is Economics not an Evolutionary Science , which coins the term Evolutionary economics , making use of anthropology to deny that there is a universal human nature, emphasizing the conflict between “industrial” or instrumental and “pecuniary” or ceremonial values, which became known as the Ceremonial/Instrumental Dichotomy. [50]

Joseph Alois Schumpeter (1883–1950) was an Austrian School economist and political scientist best known for his works on business cycles and innovation . He insisted on the role of the entrepreneurs in an economy. In Business Cycles: A theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the Capitalist process (1939), Schumpeter synthesized the theories about business cycles, suggesting that they could explain the economic situations. According to Schumpeter, capitalism necessarily goes through long-term cycles because it is entirely based upon scientific inventions and innovations. A phase of expansion is made possible by innovations, because they bring productivity gains and encourage entrepreneurs to invest. However, when investors have no more opportunities to invest, the economy goes into recession, several firms collapse, closures and bankruptcy occur. This phase lasts until new innovations bring a creative destruction process, i.e. they destroy old products, reduce the employment, but they allow the economy to start a new phase of growth, based upon new products and new factors of production . [50] [110]

In 1944 Hungarian-American mathematician John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern published Theory of Games and Economic Behavior , founding Game Theory , which was widely adopted by economists. In 1951 Princeton mathematician John Forbes Nash Jr. published the article Non-Cooperative Games , becoming the first to define a Nash Equilibrium for non-zero-sum games.

In 1956 American economist Robert Solow (1924–) and Australian economist Trevor Swan (1918–1989) proposed the Solow–Swan model , based on productivity, capital accumulation, population growth, and technological progress. In 1956 Swan also proposed the Swan diagram of the internal-external balance. In 1987 Solow was awarded the Nobel Economics Prize. [111] :440–41

Post World War II and globalization (mid to late 20th century) [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

John K. Galbraith (1908–2006) worked under the New Deal administration of Franklin Delano Roosevelt

Paul Samuelson (1915–2009) wrote the best selling economics texts.

history of economic thought essay questions

Kenneth Arrow (1921–)

history of economic thought essay questions

Gérard Debreu (1921–2004)

The globalization era began with the end of World War II and the rise of the U.S. as the world’s leading economic power, along with the United Nations . To prevent another global depression, the victorious U.S. forgave Germany its war debts and used its surpluses to rebuild Europe and encourage reindustrialization of Germany and Japan. In the 1960s it changed its role to recycling global surpluses. [112]

After World War II, Canadian-born John Kenneth Galbraith (1908–2006) became one of the standard bearers for pro-active government and liberal-democrat politics. In The Affluent Society (1958), Galbraith argued that voters reaching a certain material wealth begin to vote against the common good. He also argued that the “ conventional wisdom ” of the conservative consensus was not enough to solve the problems of social inequality. [113] In an age of big business, he argued, it is unrealistic to think of markets of the classical kind. They set prices and use advertising to create artificial demand for their own products, distorting people’s real preferences. Consumer preferences actually come to reflect those of corporations – a “dependence effect” – and the economy as a whole is geared to irrational goals. [114] In The New Industrial State Galbraith argued that economic decisions are planned by a private-bureaucracy, a technostructure of experts who manipulate marketing and public relations channels. This hierarchy is self-serving, profits are no longer the prime motivator, and even managers are not in control. Because they are the new planners, corporations detest risk, require steady economic and stable markets. They recruit governments to serve their interests with fiscal and monetary policy, for instance adhering to monetarist policies which enrich money-lenders in the City through increases in interest rates. While the goals of an affluent society and complicit government serve the irrational technostructure, public space is simultaneously impoverished. Galbraith paints the picture of stepping from penthouse villas onto unpaved streets, from landscaped gardens to unkempt public parks. In Economics and the Public Purpose (1973) Galbraith advocates a “new socialism” as the solution, nationalising military production and public services such as health care , introducing disciplined salary and price controls to reduce inequality. [115]

In contrast to Galbraith’s linguistic style, the post-war economics profession began to synthesize much of Keynes ‘ work with mathematical representations. Introductory university economics courses began to present economic theory as a unified whole in what is referred to as the neoclassical synthesis . “ Positive economics ” became the term created to describe certain trends and “laws” of economics that could be objectively observed and described in a value-free way, separate from “ normative economic ” evaluations and judgments.

The Paul Samuelson ‘s (1915–2009) Foundations of Economic Analysis published in 1947 was an attempt to show that mathematical methods could represent a core of testable economic theory. Samuelson started with two assumptions. First, people and firms will act to maximize their self-interested goals. Second, markets tend towards an equilibrium of prices, where demand matches supply. He extended the mathematics to describe equilibrating behavior of economic systems , including that of the then new macroeconomic theory of John Maynard Keynes . Whilst Richard Cantillon had imitated Isaac Newton ‘s mechanical physics of inertia and gravity in competition and the market, [29] the physiocrats had copied the body’s blood system into circular flow of income models, William Jevons had found growth cycles to match the periodicity of sunspots , Samuelson adapted thermodynamics formulae to economic theory. Reasserting economics as a hard science was being done in the United Kingdom also, and one celebrated “discovery”, of A. W. Phillips , was of a correlative relationship between inflation and unemployment. The workable policy conclusion was that securing full employment could be traded-off against higher inflation. Samuelson incorporated the idea of the Phillips curve into his work. His introductory textbook Economics was influential and widely adopted. It became the most successful economics text ever. Paul Samuelson was awarded the new Nobel Prize in Economics in 1970 for his merging of mathematics and political economy.

American economist Kenneth Arrow ‘s (1921–) published Social Choice and Individual Values in 1951. It consider connections between economics and political theory. It gave rise to social choice theory with the introduction of his “ Possibility Theorem “. This sparked widespread discussion over how to interpret the different conditions of the theorem and what implications it had for democracy and voting. Most controversial of his four (1963) or five (1950/1951) conditions is the independence of irrelevant alternatives . [116]

In the 1950s Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu (1921–2004) developed the Arrow–Debreu model of general equilibria . In 1963 Arrow published a paper which founded Health Economics . [ citation needed ]

In 1971 Arrow and Frank Hahn published General Competitive Analysis (1971), which reasserted a theory of general equilibrium of prices through the economy. In 1971, US President Richard Nixon ‘s had declared that “ We are all Keynesians now “, announcing wage and price controls. He lifted this from a comment by Milton Friedman in 1965 which formed a Time . [117]

International economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Paul Krugman (1953–)

history of economic thought essay questions

James E. Meade (1907–1995)

In 1951 English economist James E. Meade (1907–1995) published The Balance of Payments , volume 1 of “The Theory of International Economic Policy”, which proposed the theory of domestic divergence (internal and external balance), and promoted policy tools for governments. In 1955 he published volume 2 Trade and Welfare , which proposed the theory of the “second-best”, and promoted protectionism. He shared the 1977 Nobel Economic Prize with Bertil Ohlin.

In 1979 American economist Paul Krugman (1953–) published a paper founding New trade theory , which attempts to explain the role of increasing returns to scale and network effects in international trade. In 1991 he published a paper founding New economic geography . His textbook International Economics (2007) appears on many undergraduate reading lists. He was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2008.

Development economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Amartya Sen (1933–)

In 1954 Saint Lucian economist Sir Arthur Lewis (1915–1991) proposed the Dual Sector Model of Development Economics , which claims that capitalism expands by making use of an unlimited supply of labor from the backward non-capitalist “subsistence sector” until it reaches the Lewisian breaking point where wages begin to rise, receiving the 1979 Nobel Economics Prize.

In 1955 Russian-born American economist Simon Kuznets (1901–1985), who introduced the concept of Gross domestic product (GDP) in 1934 published an article revealing an inverted U-shaped relation between income inequality and economic growth, meaning that economic growth increases income disparity between rich and poor in poor countries, but decreases it in wealthy countries. In 1971 he received the Nobel Economics Prize.

Indian economist Amartya Sen (1933–) expressed considerable skepticism about the validity of neoclassical assumptions, and was highly critical of rational expectations theory, devoting his work to Development Economics and human rights.

In 1981, Sen published Poverty and Famines: An Essay on Entitlement and Deprivation (1981), a book in which he argued that famine occurs not only from a lack of food, but from inequalities built into mechanisms for distributing food. Sen also argued that the Bengal famine was caused by an urban economic boom that raised food prices, thereby causing millions of rural workers to starve to death when their wages did not keep up. [118]

In addition to his important work on the causes of famines, Sen’s work in the field of development economics has had considerable influence in the formulation of the “ Human Development Report “, [119] published by the United Nations Development Programme . [120] This annual publication that ranks countries on a variety of economic and social indicators owes much to the contributions by Sen among other social choice theorists in the area of economic measurement of poverty and inequality. Sen was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1998.

New Economic History (Cliometrics) [ edit ]

In 1958 American economists Alfred H. Conrad (1924–1970) and John R. Meyer (1927–2009) founded New Economic History , which in 1960 was called Cliometrics by American economist Stanley Reiter (1925–2014) after Clio , the muse of history. It uses neoclassical economic theory to reinterpret historical data, spreading throughout academia, causing economic historians untrained in economics to disappear from history departments. American cliometric economists Douglass Cecil North (1920–2015) and Robert William Fogel (1926–2013) were awarded the 1993 Nobel Economics Prize.

Public choice theory and constitutional economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

James Buchanan (1919–2013), Gordon Tullock (1922–2014)

In 1962 American economists James M. Buchanan (1919–2013) and Gordon Tullock (1922–2014) published The Calculus of Consent , which revived Public Choice Theory by differentiating politics (the rules of the game) from public policy (the strategies to adopt within the rules), founding Constitutional Economics , the economic analysis of constitutional law. Buchanan was awarded the 1986 Nobel Economics Prize.

Impossible Trinity [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Robert Mundell (1932–)

In 1962–1963 Scottish economist Marcus Fleming (1911–1976) and Canadian economist Robert Mundell (1932–) published the Mundell-Fleming Model of the Economy , an extension of the IS-LM Model to an open economy, proposing the Impossible Trinity of fixed exchange rate, free capital movement, and an independent monetary policy, only two of which can be maintained simultaneously. Mundell received the 1999 Nobel Economics Prize.

Market for corporate control [ edit ]

In 1965 American economist Henry G. Manne (1928–2015) published Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control in Journal of Political Economy , which claims that changes in the price of a share of stock in the stock market will occur more rapidly when insider trading is prohibited than when it is permitted, founding the theory of market for corporate control .

Information economics [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

George Akerlof (1940–), Joseph Stiglitz (1943–)

In 1970 George Akerlof (1940–) published the paper The Market for Lemons , founding the theory of Information Economics , receiving the 2001 Nobel Economics Prize.

Joseph E. Stiglitz (1943–) also received the Nobel Economics Prize in 2001 for his work in Information Economics . He has served as chairman of President Clinton’s Council of Economic Advisers, and as chief economist for the World Bank . Stiglitz has taught at many universities, including Columbia, Stanford, Oxford, Manchester, Yale, and MIT. In recent years he has become an outspoken critic of global economic institutions. In Making Globalization Work (2007) he offers an account of his perspectives on issues of international economics:

“The fundamental problem with the neoclassical model and the corresponding model under market socialism is that they fail to take into account a variety of problems that arise from the absence of perfect information and the costs of acquiring information, as well as the absence or imperfections in certain key risk and capital markets. The absence or imperfection can, in turn, to a large extent be explained by problems of information.” [121]

Stiglitz talks about his book Making Globalization Work here. [122]

Market design theory [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Leonid Hurwicz (1917–2008)

history of economic thought essay questions

Eric Maskin (1950–), Roger Myerson (1951–)

In 1973 Russian-American mathematician-economist Leonid Hurwicz (1917–2008) founded Market (Mechanism) Design Theory , a.k.a. Reverse Game Theory, which allows people to distinguish situations in which markets work well from those in which they do not, aiding the identification of efficient trading mechanisms, regulation schemes, and voting procedures; he developed the theory with Eric Maskin (1950–) and Roger Myerson (1951–), sharing the 2007 Nobel Economics Prize with them.

The Laffer curve and Reaganomics [ edit ]

In 1974 American economist Arthur Laffer formulated the Laffer Curve , which postulates that no tax revenue will be raised at the extreme tax rates of 0% and 100%, and that there must be at least one rate where tax revenue would be a non-zero maximum. This concept was adopted by U.S. President Ronald Reagan in the early 1980s, becoming the cornerstone of Reaganomics , which was co-founded by American economist Paul Craig Roberts .

Market regulation [ edit ]

In 1986 French economist Jean Tirole (1953-) published “Dynamic Models of Oligopoly”, followed by “The Theory of Industrial Organization” (1988), launching his quest to understand market power and regulation, resulting in the 2014 Nobel Economics Prize.

Post 2008 financial crisis (21st century) [ edit ]

history of economic thought essay questions

Carmen Reinhart (1955–) and Kenneth Rogoff (1953–)

history of economic thought essay questions

Olivier Blanchard (1948–)

In 2008, there was a financial crisis which led to a global recession. This prompted some economists to question the current orthodoxy. [ citation needed ]

One response was the Keynesian Resurgence . This emerged as a consensus among some policy makers and economists for a Keynesian solutions. As contrasted sharply with the previous economic orthodoxy in its support for government intervention in the economy. Figures in this school included Dominique Strauss-Kahn , Olivier Blanchard , Gordon Brown , Paul Krugman , and Martin Wolf . [123] [124] [125]

Austerity was another response, the policy of reducing government budget deficits . Austerity policies may include spending cuts, tax increases, or a mixture of both. [126] [127] Two influential academic papers support this position. The first was Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes Versus Spending , published in October 2009 by Alberto Alesina and Silvia Ardagna . It asserted that fiscal austerity measures did not hurt economies, and actually helped their recovery. [128] The second Growth in a Time of Debt , published in 2010 by Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff . It analyzed public debt and GDP growth among 20 advanced economies and claimed that high debt countries grew at −0.1% since WWII. Many governments accepted this and followed the austerity course. [ citation needed ]

In April 2013 the IMF and the Roosevelt Institute exposed basic calculation flaws in the Reinhart-Rogoff paper, claiming that when the flaws were corrected, the growth of the “high debt” countries was +2.2%, much higher than the original paper predicted. Following this, on June 6, 2013 Paul Krugman published How the Case for Austerity Has Crumbled in The New York Review of Books , arguing that the case for austerity was fundamentally flawed, and calling for an end to austerity measures. [129]

See also [ edit ]

  • Corporate law
  • Economic history
  • Energy economics
  • Index of international trade topics
  • List of economics journals
  • List of economists
  • List of important publications in economics
  • Outline of economics
  • Perspectives on capitalism
  • Timeline of international trade

Notes [ edit ]

  • ^ Kangle transliterates this word as Anviksiki , and states that this term may be better conceptualized as science of reasoning rather than full philosophy, in ancient Indian traditions; See: Kangle’s Part III [5]

References [ edit ]

  • ^ “www.historyhaven.com” . Archived from the original on 30 September 2015 . Retrieved 15 September 2015 .
  • ^ Wang, Robin R. (24 September 2012). Yinyang: The Way of Heaven and Earth in Chinese Thought and Culture . ISBN   9781139536219 . Retrieved 12 April 2015 .
  • ^ “Golden Rules-Tao Zhu Gong’s Art of Business” . Asiapac Books. Archived from the original on 29 August 2015 . Retrieved 12 April 2015 .
  • ^ Journal of the American Oriental Society (1964). “The Date of the Arthaśāstra”. 84 (2): 162–169.
  • ^ Kangle 1969 , pp. 99-100.
  • ^ Olivelle 2013 , pp. 66-69.
  • ^ David Held, Models of Democracy (Polity, 2006) 3rd Ed., pp. 11 ff.
  • ^ Chpt 1 Graeco-Roman Economics , History of Economic Analysis , Joseph Schumpeter , (1954)
  • ^ Aristotle, Politics Book II, Part V Archived 2011-06-29 at the Wayback Machine
  • ^ Aristotle Politics Book I, Part X Archived 2011-06-29 at the Wayback Machine
  • ^ Book I, Part III
  • ^ M. M. Austin; Vidal-Naquet, Pierre (1980). Economic and Social History of Ancient Greece . University of California Press. ISBN   9780520042674 . Retrieved 11 April 2012 .
  • ^ Amemiya, Takeshi. Economy and Economics of Ancient Greece . Taylor & Francis, 7 May 2007.
  • ^ Aristotle, Politics Book I, Part XI Archived 2011-06-29 at the Wayback Machine
  • ^ Aristotle, Politics Book I, Part IX Archived 2011-06-29 at the Wayback Machine
  • ^ Jump up to: a b Mochrie (2005) p. 5
  • ^ Muqaddimah 2 1995 p 30
  • ^ Spengler, Joseph J. (April 1964). “Economic Thought of Islam: Ibn Khaldun”. Comparative Studies in Society and History . Comparative Studies in Society and History vol 6 no. 3. 6 (3): 268–306. doi : 10.1017/S0010417500002164 . JSTOR   177577 .
  • ^ Toynbee, Arnold J. A Study of History . III . Royal Institute of International Affairs and Oxford University Press. p. 321. ASIN   B000OF48G8 .
  • ^ Lovewell, Mark. “Advancing Economic Thought: Rise and Fall: Ibn Khaldun and the Effects of Taxation: Ibn Khaldun and his Influence” . Wayback Machine. Archived from the original on 8 June 2003 . Retrieved 9 April 2015 . This article, which is a supplement to Understanding Economics (McGraw-Hill Ryerson, 1998), describes the early Arab historian Ibn Khaldun’s views of taxation, and their parallels with the modern-day Laffer Curve.
  • ^ “Mercantilism,” Laura LaHaye The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (2008)
  • ^ Fusfeld (1994) p. 15
  • ^ Islamic and European Expansion: The Forging of a Global Order , Michael Adas , Temple University Press (Philadelphia, PA), 1993.
  • ^ Chapra, Muhammad Umer (2014). Morality and Justice in Islamic Economics and Finance . Edward Elgar Publishing. pp. 62–63. ISBN   9781783475728 .
  • ^ Böröcz, József (10 September 2009). The European Union and Global Social Change . Routledge . p. 21. ISBN   9781135255800 . Retrieved 26 June 2017 .
  • ^ Pandey, Ishat (2017). The Sketch of The Mughal Empire . Lulu Publishers . ISBN   9780359221202 .
  • ^ Subrahmanyam, Sanjay (1998). Money and the Market in India, 1100–1700 . Oxford University Press. ISBN   9780521257589 .
  • ^ Jamal Malik (2008), Islam in South Asia: A Short History, Brill Academic, ISBN   978-9004168596 , pp. 194-197
  • ^ Jump up to: a b Fusfeld (1994) p. 21
  • ^ Locke (1689) Chapter 9, section 124
  • ^ Locke (1689) Chapter 5, sections 26–27 .
  • ^ Locke (1691) Considerations Part I, Thirdly
  • ^ Murray N. Rothbard An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, vol. 1, Economic Thought Before Adam Smith (1995) Archived 2014-09-14 at the Wayback Machine Ludwig von Mises Institute Retrieved 2012-05-16
  • ^ Sarah B. Pomeroy, Xénophon – Xenophon, Oeconomicus: a social and historical commentary Clarendon Press, 1994 Retrieved 2012-05-16
  • ^ Strong’s Concordances Archived 2012-06-25 at the Wayback Machine Biblos & The NAS New Testament Greek Lexicon (Strong’s Number: 3624) Archived 2012-04-27 at the Wayback Machine Bible Study Tools – Retrieved 2012-05-16
  • ^ Douglas Harper Etymology online Archived 2014-09-14 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved 2012-05-16
  • ^ M. I. Finley (was Professor of Ancient History and Master of Darwin College at Cambridge University) The Ancient Economy University of California Press, 1 Jan 1989, Retrieved 2012-05-16
  • ^ Edwin Cannan (editor) Adam Smith – Lectures On Justice, Police, Revenue And Arms Kessinger Publishing, 30 Apr 2004 Retrieved 2012-05-16
  • ^ Danbom (1997) Rural Development Perspectives, vol. 12, no. 1 p. 15 Archived 2007-09-27 at the Wayback Machine Why Americans Value Rural Life by David B. Danbom
  • ^ Jump up to: a b Fusfeld (1994) p. 24
  • ^ Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 2, para 2
  • ^ Jump up to: a b Smith (1776) p. 533
  • ^ Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 5, para 1
  • ^ Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 7, para 9
  • ^ Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 10, para 82
  • ^ Smith (1776) Book I, Chapter 7, para 26
  • ^ Hague (2004) pp. 187, 292
  • ^ Stephen (1898) p. 8.”
  • ^ Bentham (1791) Chapter I, para I
  • ^ Jump up to: a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p “SCHOOLS OF THOUGHT” . New School. Archived from the original on 29 June 2011 . Retrieved 23 March 2015 .
  • ^ Fusfeld (1994) p. 47
  • ^ Jump up to: a b c “The Classical School” . New School. Archived from the original on 29 June 2011 . Retrieved 23 March 2015 .
  • ^ David Ricardo Archived 2006-05-02 at the Wayback Machine , Economic History Services
  • ^ David Ricardo’s Contributions to Economics Archived 2009-02-23 at the Wayback Machine , The Victorian Web
  • ^ John Stuart Mill: Overview Archived 2009-04-13 at the Wayback Machine , The Internet Encyclopedia of Philosophy.
  • ^ Pressman (2006) p. 44
  • ^ Keynes (1936) Chapter 1, footnote
  • ^ In Marx’s words, “the exchange of commodities is evidently an act characterized by a total abstraction from use value.”
  • ^ Marx (1867) Volume I, Part I, Chapter 1, Section 4, para 123
  • ^ Marx (1867) Volume I, Part III, Chapter 9, Section 1
  • ^ Samuelson, Paul (1966). The collected scientific papers of Paul A. Samuelson . Cambridge, Mass: M.I.T. Press. ISBN   9780262190800 .
  • ^ Principles of Economics , by Alfred Marshall
  • ^ Buchholz (1989) p. 151
  • ^ Veblen, Thorstein Bunde; “The Preconceptions of Economic Science” Pt III, Quarterly Journal of Economics v14 (1900).
  • ^ Colander, David; The Death of Neoclassical Economics .
  • ^ Menger, Carl (1871) Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre , full text in html Archived 2014-09-14 at the Wayback Machine
  • ^ Law, legislation and liberty (1970)
  • ^ “Biography of F. A. Hayek (1899–1992)” . Archived from the original on 30 June 2009 . Retrieved 26 June 2009 .
  • ^ “The Austrian School” . New School. Archived from the original on 23 July 2011 . Retrieved 23 March 2015 .
  • ^ Stabile, Donald R. “Veblen and the Political Economy of the Engineer: the radical thinker and engineering leaders came to technocratic ideas at the same time”, American Journal of Economics and Sociology (45:1) 1986, 43–44.
  • ^ “The Engineers and the Price System” (PDF) . Archived (PDF) from the original on 13 November 2012 . Retrieved 29 March 2013 .
  • ^ Berle (1967) p. xxiii
  • ^ Martinez-Alier, J. 1987. Ecological economics. Blackwell, Oxford.
  • ^ Schumacher, E.F. 1973. Small Is Beautiful: A Study of Economics As If People Mattered . Blond and Briggs, London.
  • ^ Daly, H. 1991. Steady-State Economics (2nd ed.). Island Press, Washington, D.C.
  • ^ Daly, H. E. 1999. Ecological Economics and the Ecology of Economics . E Elgar Publications, Cheltenham.
  • ^ Daly, H.E. and Cobb, J. B. 1989. For the Common.
  • ^ Paehlke R. (1995). Conservation and Environmentalism: An Encyclopedia, p. 315 . Taylor & Francis.
  • ^ Malte Faber. (2008). How to be an ecological economist. Ecological Economics 66 (1):1–7. Preprint Archived 2015-06-29 at the Wayback Machine .
  • ^ “Economy and Thermodynamics” . Archived from the original on 20 October 2014 . Retrieved 5 September 2014 .
  • ^ The Energy Certificate essay by Fezer. An article on Energy Accounting as proposed by Technocracy Inc. http://www.technocracy.org/Archives/The%20Energy%20Certificate-r.htm [ permanent dead link ]
  • ^ Tainter, Joseph A. (1990). The Collapse of Complex Societies (1st paperback ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN   0-521-38673-X .
  • ^ Keynes (1919) The Economic Consequences of the Peace
  • ^ Keynes (1919) Chapter III, para 20
  • ^ Keynes (1919) Chapter V, para 43
  • ^ Keynes (1919) Chapter VI, para 4
  • ^ Keynes (1919) Chapter VII, para 7
  • ^ Keynes (1919) Chapter VII, para 30
  • ^ Keynes (1919) Chapter VII, para 48
  • ^ Keynes (1919) Chapter VII, para 58
  • ^ e.g. Etienne Mantioux (1946) The Carthaginian Peace, or the Economic Consequences of Mr. Keynes
  • ^ See, e.g., Donald Markwell , John Maynard Keynes and International Relations : Economic Paths to War and Peace , Oxford University Press, 2006.
  • ^ Keynes (1923) Chapter 3
  • ^ This was not accepted by the United States Congress at the time, but arose later through the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade of 1947 and the World Trade Organization of 1994
  • ^ Mankiw, 1655.
  • ^ Mankiw, 1657.
  • ^ Huw Dixon, A simple model of imperfect competition with Walrasian features, Oxford Economic Papers, 1987, 39, 134–60
  • ^ Costa L, Dixon H. (2011), “Fiscal Policy Under Imperfect Competition with Flexible Prices: An Overview and Survey”, Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, Vol. 5, 2011-3. doi : 10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2011-3 . [1]
  • ^ L. Randall Wray, ed. (2004). Credit and State Theories of Money: The Contributions of A. Mitchell Innes . Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN   978-1-84376-513-4 .
  • ^ Sturges v Bridgman (1879) 11 Ch D 852
  • ^ Coase (1960) IV, 7
  • ^ Coase (1960) V, 9
  • ^ Coase (1960) VIII, 23
  • ^ Friedman (1967) p.
  • ^ “Charlie Rose Show”. 26 December 2005. Missing or empty |series= ( help )
  • ^ Mankiw, 1647–48.
  • ^ Manikw, N. Greg. “A Quick Refresher Course in Macroeconomics.” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 28 , No. 4. (Dec., 1990), p. 1647.
  • ^ Mankiw, 1649.
  • ^ Mankiw, 1653.
  • ^ Alessandro Roncaglia . The wealth of ideas: a history of economic thought . Cambridge University Press. 2005. ISBN   978-0-521-84337-9 . p. 431
  • ^ Screpanti; Ernesto; Zamagni; Stefano (2005). An Outline of the History of Economic Thought’ (2nd ed.). Oxford University Press.
  • ^ Varoufakis, Yanis (30 July 2013). “Is Europe’s Complacency America’s Fault?” . the globalist. Archived from the original on 28 March 2017 . Retrieved 27 March 2017 .
  • ^ Galbraith (1958) Chapter 2; n.b. though Galbraith claimed to coin the phrase “conventional wisdom”, the phrase is used several times in Thorstein Veblen ‘s book The Instinct of Workmanship .
  • ^ Galbraith (1958) Chapter 11
  • ^ “Conversations with History: John Kenneth Galbraith” . YouTube. 12 June 2008. Archived from the original on 9 October 2013 . Retrieved 29 March 2013 .
  • ^ “What can be done to improve the current situation? Regulation vs deregulation and lessons learnt from previous financial crisis” . YouTube. 13 January 2009. Archived from the original on 1 August 2013 . Retrieved 29 March 2013 .
  • ^ “Archived copy” . Archived from the original on 4 November 2007 . Retrieved 30 September 2007 .
  • ^ Sachs, Jeffrey (26 October 1998). “The real causes of famine: a Nobel laureate blames authoritarian rulers” . Time . Archived from the original on 15 July 2014 . Retrieved 16 June 2014 .
  • ^ United Nations Development Programme, UNDP , ed. (2010). “Overview | Celebrating 20 years of human development”. Human Development Report 2010 | 20th anniversary edition | the real wealth of nations: pathways to human development . New York, NY: United Nations Development Programme. p. 2. ISBN   9780230284456 . …the first HDR called for a different approach to economics and development – one that put people at the centre. The approach was anchored in a new vision of development, inspired by the creative passion and vision of Mahbub ul Haq, the lead author of the early HDRs, and the ground-breaking work of Amartya Sen. Pdf version. Archived 2016-07-22 at the Wayback Machine
  • ^ Batterbury, Simon; Fernando, Jude (2004), “Amartya Sen”, in Hubbard, Phil; Kitchin, Rob; Valentine, Gill (eds.), Key thinkers on space and place , London: Sage, pp. 251–57, ISBN   9780761949626 . Draft Archived 2016-03-04 at the Wayback Machine
  • ^ Stiglitz (1996) p. 5
  • ^ “Authors@Google: Joseph Stiglitz” . YouTube. 13 October 2006. Archived from the original on 15 February 2013 . Retrieved 29 March 2013 .
  • ^ Bateman, Bradley; Toshiaki, Hirai; Marcuzzo, Maria Cristina (2010). The Return to Keynes . Harvard University Press . ISBN   978-0-674-03538-6 .
  • ^ Henry Farrell and John Quiggin (March 2012). “Consensus, Dissensus and Economic Ideas: The Rise and Fall of Keynesianism During the Economic Crisis” (PDF) . The Center for the Study of Development Strategies. Archived from the original (PDF) on 25 August 2013 . Retrieved 29 May 2012 .
  • ^ Giles, Chris; Atkins, Ralph; Guha, Krishna. “The undeniable shift to Keynes” . The Financial Times . Archived from the original on 27 May 2009 . Retrieved 23 January 2009 .
  • ^ “Austerity measure” . Financial Times Lexicon . Archived from the original on 22 March 2013 . Retrieved 1 March 2013 .
  • ^ Traynor, Ian; Allen, Katie (11 June 2010). “Austerity Europe: who faces the cuts” . London: Guardian News. Archived from the original on 15 September 2013 . Retrieved 29 September 2010 .
  • ^ “Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes Versus Spending” . NBER . Archived from the original on 3 April 2015 . Retrieved 24 March 2015 .
  • ^ “How the Case for Austerity Has Crumbled by Paul Krugman” . Archived from the original on 28 March 2015 . Retrieved 24 March 2015 .

Primary sources [ edit ]

  • Aquinas, Thomas (1274). Summa Theologica
  • Aristotle (c. 350 BC). Nicomachean Ethics
  • Aristotle (c. 350 BC). Politics
  • Arrow, Kenneth J (1951). Social Choice and Individual Values , 2nd Ed. 1963, Wiley, New York, ISBN   0-300-01364-7
  • Arrow, Kenneth J. and Frank Hahn (1971). General Competitive Analysis , Holden-Day, San Francisco, ISBN   0-8162-0275-3
  • Bentham, Jeremy (1776). Fragment on Government
  • Bentham, Jeremy (1789). An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation
  • Burke, Edmund (1790). Reflections on the Revolution in France
  • Burke, Edmund. (1795). Thoughts and Details on Scarcity
  • Cantillon, Richard (1732). Essay on the Nature of Commerce in General
  • Coase, Ronald . (1937). “The Nature of the Firm” Economica , Vol. 4, Issue 16, pp. 386–405
  • Coase, Ronald H. (1960) “The Problem of Social Cost” (this online version excludes some parts) Journal of Law and Economics , Vol.3, pp. 1–44
  • Commons, John R. (1934). Institutional Economics New York: Macmillan
  • Engels, Friedrich (1845). Condition of the Working Class in England in 1844
  • Friedman, Milton (1953) Essays in Positive Economics : Part I – The Methodology of Positive Economics , University of Chicago
  • Galbraith, J.K. (1958). The Affluent Society , 3rd Ed. reprinted 1991, Penguin Books, ISBN   014013610X
  • Galbraith, J.K. (1967) . The New Industrial State
  • Galbraith, J.K. (1973). Economics and the Public Purpose
  • Hobbes, Thomas (1651). Leviathan
  • Hume, David (1777). Essays, Moral, Political, Literary
  • Jevons, William (1871). The Theory of Political Economy
  • Jevons, William (1878). The Periodicity of Commercial Crises
  • Keynes, John Maynard (1919). The Economic Consequences of the Peace
  • Keynes, John Maynard. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money
  • Locke, John (1689). Second Treatise on Civil Government
  • Locke, John. (1691). Some Considerations on the consequences of the Lowering of Interest and the Raising of the Value of Money
  • Markwell, Donald (2006). John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace , Oxford.
  • Marshall, Alfred (1890). Principles of Economics
  • Marx, Karl (1871). Das Kapital
  • Mill, John Stuart (1871). Principles of Political Economy
  • Mun, Thomas (1621). A Discourse of Trade from England unto the East Indies
  • North, Dudley (1691). Discourses upon trade
  • Petty, William (1690). The Political Arithmetick
  • Quesnay, François (1758). Tableau économique
  • Ricardo, David (1827). Principles of Political Economy and Taxation
  • Robinson, Joan (1953). The Production Function and the Theory of Capital
  • Robinson, Joan. (1962). Economic Philosophy
  • Scotus, Duns (1295). Sententiae
  • Sen, Amartya (1985). “The Moral Standing of the Market”, in Ethics and Economics , ed. Ellen Frankel Paul, Fred D. Miller, Jr and Jeffrey Paul, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, pp. 1–19
  • Sen, Amartya. (1976–1977). “Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioural Foundations of Economic Theory”, Philosophy and Public Affairs , 6, pp. 317–44
  • Sen, Amartya. (1987). On Ethics and Economics Oxford, Basil Blackwell
  • Sismondi, J.-C.-L. Simonde de (1819, trans. 1991). “New Principles of Political Economy: Of Wealth in Its Relation to Population”
  • Smith, Adam (1759). The Theory of Moral Sentiments
  • Smith, Adam (1776). An Inquiry Into The Wealth of Nations
  • Sraffa, Piero (1960). Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities
  • Stigler, George J (1965). “The Nature and Role of Originality in Scientific Progress”, in Essays in the History of Economics , University of Chicago Press, pp. 1–15
  • Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1996). Whither Socialism?
  • Thornton, Henry (1802). The Paper Credit of Great Britain
  • Turgot, Jacques (1766). Réflexions sur la formation et la distribution des richesses in French and English
  • Veblen, Thorstein . The Theory of the Leisure Class: an economic study of institutions (1899)
  • Veblen, Thorsten. (1904). Theory of Business Enterprise
  • von Hörnigk, Philip (1684). Österreich Über Alles, Wenn Sie Nur Will

Secondary sources [ edit ]

  • Allen, William (1977). “Economics, Economists, and Economic Policy: Modern American Experiences”, in History of Political Economy , Volume 9, no. 1, pp. 48–88. Duke Univ Press. Reprinted in Econ Journal Watch 7[3]: pp. 235–74, Sept 2010. [2]
  • Blaug, Mark (1997). Economic Theory in Retrospect , 5th ed.. Cambridge University Press. Description & chapter links, pp. vii – xvi.
  • _____ (2001). “No History of Ideas, Please, We’re Economists”, Journal of Economic Perspectives , 15(1), pp. 145–64 (press + ).
  • Buchholz, Todd G. (1989). New Ideas from Dead Economists , New York, Penguin Group. p. 151
  • Cossa, Luigi. (1893). An Introduction to the Study of Political Economy , London and New York: Macmillan [3]
  • Danbom, David B. (1997). Why Americans Value Rural Life , Rural Development Perspectives, vol. 12, no. 1, pp. 15–18
  • Ekelund, Robert B., Jr. and Robert F. Hébert (2007). A History of Economic Theory and Method . Waveland Press. 5th ed. ISBN   1-57766-486-8 . Description.
  • Fusfeld, Daniel R. (1994). The Age of the Economist , Harper Collins, 7th Ed. ISBN   0-673-46805-4
  • Hague, William (2004). William Pitt the Younger Harper Perennial ISBN   0-00-714720-1
  • Heilbroner, Robert (1953; 1999 7th ed.). The Worldly Philosophers , Simon & Schuster. ISBN   0-684-86214-X
  • Lee, Frederic S. (2009). A History of Heterodox Economics: Challenging the Mainstream in the Twentieth Century , Routledge. Description .
  • Macfie, Alec Lawrence (1955). “The Scottish Tradition in Economic Thought”. Econ Journal Watch 6(3): 389–410. Reprinted from Scottish Journal of Political Economy 2(2): 81–103 [4]
  • Markwell, Donald (2006). John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace , Oxford University Press.
  • Markwell, Donald (2000). Keynes and Australia , Reserve Bank of Australia . [1]
  • Medema, Steven G., and Warren J. Samuels (2003). The History of Economic Thought: A Reader . Routledge. Description & chapter-preview links.
  • Mochrie, Robert (2005). Justice in Exchange: The Economic Philosophy of John Duns Scotus [ permanent dead link ]
  • Nicola, PierCarlo (2000). Mainstream Mathematical Economics in the 20th Century . Springer. ISBN   978-3-540-67084-1 .
  • Nasar, Sylvia (2011). Grand Pursuit: The Story of Economic Genius , Simon & Schuster. Description and excerpt .
  • From The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2008), 2nd Edition. Abstract links for:
  • Pressman, Steven (2006). Fifty Major Economists , Routledge, ISBN   0-415-36649-6
  • Ptak, Justin (n.d.). “ The Prehistory of Modern Economic Thought: The Aristotle in Austrian Theory “
  • Rothbard, Murray (1995). An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought , von Mises Institute, ISBN   978-0945466482
  • Samuelson, Paul A. and William A. Barnett , ed. (2007). Inside the Economist’s Mind: Conversations with Eminent Economists , Wiley. Description , contents , and preview .
  • Screpanti, Ernesto and Zamagni, Stefano (2005). An Outline of the History of Economic Thought , 2nd ed. Oxford University Press. Description & ch.-preview links, pp. xi – xviii.
  • Schumpeter, Joseph (1954). History of Economic Analysis , Description. Chapter-preview links for Parts I – V (arrow-page searchable). Routledge Ed. 1994, ISBN   0-415-10892-6
  • Spengler, Joseph J. , and William R. Allen, ed. (1960). Essays in Economic Thought: Aristotle to Marshall . Rand McNally.
  • Spiegel, Henry William (1971; 1991 3rd ed.). The Growth of Economic Thought , Duke University Press. ISBN   0-8223-0965-3
  • Stephen, Leslie (1898). “Smith, Adam”  . Dictionary of National Biography . London: Smith, Elder & Co. 1885–1900.
  • Stigler, George J. (1965). Essays in the History of Economics . University of Chicago Press.
  • Weintraub, E. Roy (1999). “How Should We Write the History of Twentieth-Century Economics?” Oxford Review of Economic Policy , 15(4), pp. 139–52 .
  • (2002). How Economics Became a Mathematical Science . Duke University Press. Description and preview .

Further reading [ edit ]

Books [ edit ].

  • A History of Economic Thought [1929] Isaak Illich Rubin .
  • The History of Economic Thought , (1938, and subsequent editions), Eric Roll .
  • A History of Economic Thought , (1967, and subsequent editions), William J. Barber.
  • Kazanas, N. 2010. Economic principles in the Vedic tradition. New Delhi: Aditya Prakashan.
  • Majumdar, R. C. 2010. Corporate life in ancient India. Charleston, SC: Bibliolife.
  • An Outline of the History of Economic Thought (2nd Edition) , (2003) Ernesto Screpanti and Stefano Zamagni
  • The Penguin History of Economics , (2002), Roger Backhouse (economist) .
  • Blaug, Mark (1985). Economic Theory in Retrospect (PDF contains full book) (4th ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN   978-0521316446 .

Journals [ edit ]

  • European Journal of the History of Economic Thought (U.K.)
  • History of Economic Ideas (Italy)
  • I l pensiero economico italiano (Italy)
  • History of Economics Review (Australia)
  • History of Economic Thought (Japan)
  • History of Political Economy (U.S.)
  • Journal of the History of Economic Thought (published by the History of Economics Society )
  • A list of other history of economic thought journals was compiled by the Italian Society for the History of Political Economy (STOREP) : check it here

Societies for the History of Economic Thought [ edit ]

  • European Society for the History of Economic Thought (ESHET)
  • History of Economics Society (HES)
  • List of other societies and research centers in history of economic thought is available here

External links [ edit ]

  • “The History of Economic Thought Website” . Archived from the original on March 2, 2010 . Retrieved March 12, 2014 .
  • Archive for the History of Economic Thought
  • “Family tree” of economics poster from the 16th century on.
  • Pioneers of the social sciences London School of Economics and Political Science

Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.

To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to  upgrade your browser .

Enter the email address you signed up with and we'll email you a reset link.

  • We're Hiring!
  • Help Center

paper cover thumbnail

A Brief History of Economic Thought: A Review Essay

Profile image of Alex M. Thomas

2019, Artha Vijnana

A review essay of Alessandro Roncaglia’s A Brief History of Economic Thought (2017).

RELATED PAPERS

Andrea Ginzburg

Yoshinori Shiozawa

Stefano Lucarelli

Matias Vernengo

Economic Systems Research

mathtam purista

Artha Vijnana

Alex M. Thomas

MUSTAPHA NASIR USMAN

Joshua Opeyemi Olorunsaiye

Sebastian Poblete Concha

Nicholas Theocarakis

Leonardo Vera

camilla yang

Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics

Thomas R Wells

Diego Campanella

Repapis, Constantinos (2018) Integrating History of Economic Thought into Introductory Economics.

Constantinos Repapis

Isaac Correa

Journal of Reviews on Global Economics

Carmelo Ferlito

Procesos de Mercado: Revista Europea de Economía Política

History of political economy

Riccardo Bellofiore

A Companion to the History of Economic Thought

John Lodewijks

Annals of the Fondazione Luigi Einaudi

Anna Carabelli

Dimitris Katsaros

Teacher Plus

Journal of Economic Methodology

Hector Alexander Alba Avelino

RELATED TOPICS

  •   We're Hiring!
  •   Help Center
  • Find new research papers in:
  • Health Sciences
  • Earth Sciences
  • Cognitive Science
  • Mathematics
  • Computer Science
  • Academia ©2024

IMAGES

  1. PPT

    history of economic thought essay questions

  2. (PDF) A Revisionist’s View of the History of Economic Thought

    history of economic thought essay questions

  3. (PDF) Economic thought: a brief history

    history of economic thought essay questions

  4. Exam 2016, questions

    history of economic thought essay questions

  5. Essay History of economics thought, classical school of economists

    history of economic thought essay questions

  6. (PDF) Ontology and the History of Economic Thought: An Introduction

    history of economic thought essay questions

VIDEO

  1. The History of Economic Thought (Economic Ideas and Thinkers)

  2. Studying History of Economic Thought (HET)

  3. History of economic thought: Economic thought by Dr. BR Ambedkar

  4. What is History of economic thought?, Explain History of economic thought

  5. history of economic thought part

  6. #History of Economics thoughts:-Physiocracy

COMMENTS

  1. Exam 2016, questions

    HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT (15ECB016) 2015/16 Semester 2 3 hours Answer TWO questions from Section A Answer TWO questions from Section B Answer TWO questions from Section C Any approved University calculator is permitted. SECTION A (Each question is worth 10 marks). 1.

  2. History of Economic Thought Final Multiple Choice Flashcards

    Study with Quizlet and memorize flashcards containing terms like An unusual element in the classroom comparative advantage problem was that. A. One country had an absolute advantage in silver and timber B. The highest timber producer (in board fee) was also the one with the most timber C. The highest silver producer was also the one with the most silver D. Graphs were emphasized (an ...

  3. PDF AP/ECON 4069 History of Economic Thought II

    Presenting and addressing counterarguments is crucial for a grade of B or better. Your essay (1500 - 2000 words) should be based on ALL of your readings and lectures in 4059 and 4069 and your two summaries of the opposing positions in the short reading response paper and Question 1 above. From your summaries of opposing positions, only ...

  4. PDF take-home exam 2013

    There are two essay questions. Question 1 is worth 25% of your final course grade. Question 2 is worth 10%. You must answer both. 1. The classical economists we have studied - Steuart, the Physiocrats, Smith, Ricardo, Marx - shared, to a large extent, a vision of the emerging capitalist economic system. Thomas Kuhn defines normal science as ...

  5. PDF History of Economic Thought

    This course introduces key Western economic thinkers but challenges a Eurocentric narration by juxtaposing them with ancient Chinese and Islamic traditions of economic thought. Core goals are (1) to have students understand and analyse key concepts and thinkers in the history of economic thought; and (2) to enable students to use concepts from ...

  6. Economics 493/593

    Practice Essay Questions - Midterm 1 (Updated) Review Questions for Midterm 1. Economics 493/593. Fall 2007. 1. Why does the book choose to begin the study of the evolution of economic thought around the year 1500? 2. What factors were important in the transition from feudalism to capitalism?

  7. PDF History of Economic Thought Econ 1200

    lineages of ideas for contemporary economics. Prerequisite intermediate microeconomics (Econ 1110 or 1130). Learning Goals . Studying the history of economic thought provides students with a depth of knowledge of the scholars and ideas that have shaped the discipline and discourse around how we model, understand, and interpret economic activity.

  8. PDF ECON 4560: History of Economic Thought. Spring 2023

    the Best Book Award from the European Society for the History of Economic Thought. Rodrigo Morales Mendoza (RMM) is a PhD candidate in Economics at UPenn. He is originally from Mexico City. His research interests include the mathematical tools and machine learning envi-ronments applied to macroeconomic questions. 1

  9. Essay Writing

    Discusses primary and secondary sources; questions to consider when reading primary historical documents; and how to develop a manageable topic. Online Books (A Selective List): The Student's Guide to Writing Economics by Robert Neugeboren

  10. Assessment Materials in History of Economic Thought

    History of Economic Thought, UMKC. Fred Lee, University of Missouri-Kansas City. Paper assignment for a History of Economic Thought module for 2nd and 3rd year students. Published or updated: 2010. Licence: Creative Commons Attribution NonCommercial (CC-BY-NC)

  11. The history of economic thought and its role in rethinking economics

    This essay was written in honour of the great Mark Blaug (1927-2011). It defends the relevance of the history of economic thought for modern research. Since economics is, after all, a social ...

  12. PDF HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT I (Eco 307) Lecture Notes Introduction and

    The History and development of economic ideas can be studied under three (3) periods, namely; 1. Ancient 2. Medieval and 3. Modern Ancient Greek writers such as the philosopher Aristotle examined ideas about the art of wealth acquisition, and questioned whether property is best left in private or public hands.

  13. History of economic thought

    The history of economic thought is the study of the philosophies of the different thinkers and theories in ... Questions 77 and 78 concern economic issues, primarily what a ... imitated Newton's forces of inertia and gravity in the natural world with human reason and market competition in the economic world. In his Essay on the Nature of ...

  14. PDF History of Economic Thought

    History of Economic Thought Craufurd D. Goodwin Abstract Attention was paid to the history of economic thought (HET) by pioneers of economics such ... market made up of only one essay in HET and two in more saleable fields. External funding for ... thinkers on questions with which they were engaged; for example, they often denigrated the

  15. Model Questions on History of Economic Thought I-Mercantilism ...

    One of the following is not true about the economic school of thought of 1776-1848? A. Classical economics is expounded between John Stuart Mill of "principles of political economy" and Adam smith of "Wealth of Nations" B. Classists proposed system of economic theories that are sharp opposite with the earlier trends of thought. C.

  16. History of Economic Thought

    The module is designed to first present some of the main schools of thought from a historical and methodological perspective. Each week we explore and critically assess the main tenants of each school of thought. In the second part of the module we link history of economic thought and methodology to a specific and contemporary economic question.

  17. Economics: History of Economic Thought

    Explore the history of economic thought over the period 1700-1914. This collection contains primary and secondary resources, including full books, selected chapters, and journal articles, as well as new thematic essays, and subject introductions on key themes. Coverage: varies, contains primary sources. Full text.

  18. History of Economic Thought

    The history of economic thought deals with different thinkers and theories in the subject that became political economy and economics, from the ancient world to the present day in the 21st Century.. This field encompasses many disparate schools of economic thought.. Ancient Greek writers such as the philosopher Aristotle examined ideas about the art of wealth acquisition and questioned whether ...

  19. History of Economic Thought Exam 1 Flashcards

    1. Gold & silver is the most desirable form of wealth. 2. Nationalism (and thus, militarism) 3. Inflows of gold (exports) became desirable, outflows of gold (imports) became undesirable. 4. Colonization & monopolization of colonial trade. 5.

  20. History of Economic Thought

    Aug 26, 2023. Answer. There are two main sources of economic growth: growth in the size of the workforce and growth in the productivity (output per hour worked) of that workforce. Either can ...

  21. A Brief History of Economic Thought: A Review Essay

    This review essay is also intended to serve as a roadmap for HET courses by underscoring important conceptual issues and themes in the history of economic thought as well as broader concerns like the sociology of economic thought. In 2016, Heinz Kurz, one of the foremost historians of economic thought, published Economic Thought: A Brief ...