IMF: Why research and development is a crucial part of economic growth

A man looking through a microscope.

Analysis suggests that the composition of R&D matters for growth. Image:  Unsplash/Lucas Vasques

.chakra .wef-1c7l3mo{-webkit-transition:all 0.15s ease-out;transition:all 0.15s ease-out;cursor:pointer;-webkit-text-decoration:none;text-decoration:none;outline:none;color:inherit;}.chakra .wef-1c7l3mo:hover,.chakra .wef-1c7l3mo[data-hover]{-webkit-text-decoration:underline;text-decoration:underline;}.chakra .wef-1c7l3mo:focus,.chakra .wef-1c7l3mo[data-focus]{box-shadow:0 0 0 3px rgba(168,203,251,0.5);} Philip Barrett

Diaa noureldin, jean-marc natal, niels-jakob hansen.

how can research help in fostering economic growth

.chakra .wef-9dduvl{margin-top:16px;margin-bottom:16px;line-height:1.388;font-size:1.25rem;}@media screen and (min-width:56.5rem){.chakra .wef-9dduvl{font-size:1.125rem;}} Explore and monitor how .chakra .wef-15eoq1r{margin-top:16px;margin-bottom:16px;line-height:1.388;font-size:1.25rem;color:#F7DB5E;}@media screen and (min-width:56.5rem){.chakra .wef-15eoq1r{font-size:1.125rem;}} COVID-19 is affecting economies, industries and global issues

A hand holding a looking glass by a lake

.chakra .wef-1nk5u5d{margin-top:16px;margin-bottom:16px;line-height:1.388;color:#2846F8;font-size:1.25rem;}@media screen and (min-width:56.5rem){.chakra .wef-1nk5u5d{font-size:1.125rem;}} Get involved with our crowdsourced digital platform to deliver impact at scale

Stay up to date:, emerging technologies.

  • Analysis by the IMF suggests that research and development are vital for economic progress.
  • Cross-border collaboration is also crucial to help foster the innovation needed for long-term growth.
  • COVID-19 vaccines are an example of innovation, helping save lives and bring forward the reopening of many economies.

The pandemic has rolled back decades of economic progress and wrought havoc on public finances. To build back better and fight climate change, sizable public investment needs to be sustainably financed. Boosting long-term growth—and thereby tax revenue—has rarely felt more pressing.

But what are the drivers of long-term growth? Productivity—the ability to create more outputs with the same inputs—is an important one. In our latest World Economic Outlook , we emphasize the role of innovation in stimulating long-term productivity growth . Surprisingly, productivity growth has been declining for decades in advanced economies despite steady increases in research and development (R&D), a proxy for innovation effort.

Knowledge transfer between countries is an important driver of innovation.

Our analysis suggests that the composition of R&D matters for growth. We find that basic scientific research affects more sectors, in more countries and for a longer time than applied research (commercially oriented R&D by firms), and that for emerging market and developing economies, access to foreign research is especially important. Easy technology transfer, cross-border scientific collaboration and policies that fund basic research can foster the kind of innovation we need for long-term growth.

Inventions draw on basic scientific knowledge

While applied research is important to bring innovations to market, basic research expands the knowledge base needed for breakthrough scientific progress. A striking example is the development of COVID-19 vaccines, which in addition to saving millions of lives has helped bring forward the reopening of many economies, potentially injecting trillions into the global economy . Like other major innovations, scientists drew on decades of accumulated knowledge in different fields to develop the mRNA vaccines.

Basic research is not tied to a particular product or country and can be combined in unpredictable ways and used in different fields. This means that it spreads more widely and remains relevant for a longer time than applied knowledge. This is evident from the difference in citations between scientific articles used for basic research, and patents (applied research). Citations for scientific articles peak at about eight years versus three years for patents.

Have you read?

How to find the best work-life balance for you, according to science, science denial: why it happens and 5 things you can do about it, this ‘citizen science’ project means anyone can help map the great barrier reef - from the comfort of home.

Relevant for longer

Spillovers are important for emerging markets and developing economies

While the bulk of basic research is conducted in advanced economies, our analysis suggests that knowledge transfer between countries is an important driver of innovation, especially in emerging market and developing economies.

Emerging market and developing economies rely much more on foreign than homegrown research (basic and applied) for innovation and growth. In countries where education systems are strong and financial markets deep, the estimated effect of foreign technology adoption on productivity growth—through trade, foreign direct investment or learning-by-doing—is particularly large. As such, emerging market and developing economies may find that policies to adapt foreign knowledge to local conditions are a better avenue for development than investing directly in homegrown basic research.

Knowledge spillovers

We gauge this by looking at data on research stocks —measures of accumulated knowledge through research expenditure. As the chart shows, a 1-percentage-point increase in foreign basic knowledge increases annual patenting in emerging market and developing economies by around 0.9 percentage point more than in advanced economies.

Innovation is a key driver of productivity growth

Why does patenting matter? It’s a proxy for measuring innovation. An increase in the stock of patents by 1 percent can increase productivity per worker by 0.04 percent. That may not sound like much, but it adds up. Small increases over time improve living standards.

We estimate that a 10 percent permanent increase in the stock of a country’s own basic research can increase productivity by 0.3 percent. The impact of the same increase in the stock of foreign basic research is larger. Productivity increases by 0.6 percent. Because these are average numbers only, the impact on emerging markets and developing economies is likely to be even bigger.

Basic science also plays a larger role in green innovation (including renewables) than in dirty technologies (such as gas turbines), suggesting that policies to boost basic research can help tackle climate change.

The Young Scientists Community , founded in 2008, brings together extraordinary rising-star scientists from various academic disciplines and geographies, all under the age of 40. Their mission is to help leaders engage with science and the role it plays in society.

The World Economic Forum trains and empowers Young Scientists to communicate cutting-edge research and champion evidence-based decision making, and in doing so, helps build a diverse global community of next-generation scientific leaders.

how can research help in fostering economic growth

Each year, the Forum selects and onboards a new class of Young Scientists, adding to the growing 400+ alumni community. Meet the 2020 Young Scientists tackling the world’s most pressing challenges through scientific innovation. Get in touch to find out more about the community.

Return on investment.

Policies for a more buoyant and inclusive future

Because private firms can only capture a small part of the uncertain financial reward of engaging in basic research, they tend to underinvest in it, providing a strong case for public policy intervention. But designing the right policies—including determining how you fund research—can be tricky. For example, funding basic research only at universities and public labs could be inefficient. Potentially important synergies between the private and public sector would be lost. It may also be difficult to disentangle basic and applied private research for the sake of subsidizing only the former.

Our analysis shows that an implementable hybrid policy that doubles subsidies to private research (basic and applied alike) and boosts public research expenditure by a third could increase productivity growth in advanced economies by 0.2 percentage point a year. Better targeting of subsidies to basic research and closer public‑private cooperation could boost this even further, at lower cost for public finances.

These investments would start to pay for themselves within about a decade and would have a sizeable impact on incomes. We estimate that per capita incomes would be about 12 percent higher than they are now had these investments been made between 1960 and 2018.

Finally, because of important spillovers to emerging markets, it is also key to ensure the free flow of ideas and collaboration across borders.

Don't miss any update on this topic

Create a free account and access your personalized content collection with our latest publications and analyses.

License and Republishing

World Economic Forum articles may be republished in accordance with the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 International Public License, and in accordance with our Terms of Use.

The views expressed in this article are those of the author alone and not the World Economic Forum.

Related topics:

The agenda .chakra .wef-n7bacu{margin-top:16px;margin-bottom:16px;line-height:1.388;font-weight:400;} weekly.

A weekly update of the most important issues driving the global agenda

.chakra .wef-1dtnjt5{display:-webkit-box;display:-webkit-flex;display:-ms-flexbox;display:flex;-webkit-align-items:center;-webkit-box-align:center;-ms-flex-align:center;align-items:center;-webkit-flex-wrap:wrap;-ms-flex-wrap:wrap;flex-wrap:wrap;} More on Emerging Technologies .chakra .wef-17xejub{-webkit-flex:1;-ms-flex:1;flex:1;justify-self:stretch;-webkit-align-self:stretch;-ms-flex-item-align:stretch;align-self:stretch;} .chakra .wef-nr1rr4{display:-webkit-inline-box;display:-webkit-inline-flex;display:-ms-inline-flexbox;display:inline-flex;white-space:normal;vertical-align:middle;text-transform:uppercase;font-size:0.75rem;border-radius:0.25rem;font-weight:700;-webkit-align-items:center;-webkit-box-align:center;-ms-flex-align:center;align-items:center;line-height:1.2;-webkit-letter-spacing:1.25px;-moz-letter-spacing:1.25px;-ms-letter-spacing:1.25px;letter-spacing:1.25px;background:none;padding:0px;color:#B3B3B3;-webkit-box-decoration-break:clone;box-decoration-break:clone;-webkit-box-decoration-break:clone;}@media screen and (min-width:37.5rem){.chakra .wef-nr1rr4{font-size:0.875rem;}}@media screen and (min-width:56.5rem){.chakra .wef-nr1rr4{font-size:1rem;}} See all

how can research help in fostering economic growth

How to build the skills needed for the age of AI

Juliana Guaqueta Ospina

April 11, 2024

how can research help in fostering economic growth

Space is booming. Here's how to embrace the $1.8 trillion opportunity

Nikolai Khlystov and Gayle Markovitz

April 8, 2024

how can research help in fostering economic growth

These 6 countries are using space technology to build their digital capabilities. Here’s how

Simon Torkington

how can research help in fostering economic growth

What is e-voting? Who’s using it and is it safe?

Victoria Masterson

April 4, 2024

how can research help in fostering economic growth

This Dubai-based company turns used cooking oil into biofuels

how can research help in fostering economic growth

4 lessons from Jane Goodall as the renowned primatologist turns 90

Gareth Francis

April 3, 2024

  • Utility Menu

University Logo

research page title

The Growth Lab hosts an interdisciplinary team that iterates between theory and practice of economic development to improve our understanding of how economies grow.

Our trademark methodologies, Economic Complexity and Growth Diagnostics, have revolutionized development thinking and inspired many places to reconsider their economic strategies.

Research Questions We Seek To Answer

What kinds of processes do countries, regions, and cities use to diversify their productive capacity and accumulate productive knowledge in order to accelerate growth?

How can migration and mobility help foster economic development and how do complementary skills impact labor market dynamics?

What is the role of special economic zones in tackling product diversification opportunities and how does it impact knowledge transfer and migration?

How can countries prioritize key policy decisions and sequencing to achieve their long-term strategy?

Search by Country Name, Project title, etc.

Academic research.

Our multidisciplinary team is working to uncover the mechanisms behind economic growth. Our three research pillars are: Economic Transformation; Diffusion of Knowledge and Technology; and Coordination of Knowhow. 

  • Publications

Policy Research

We are developing rigorous place-specific research on the constraints to sustained shared prosperity, translating these insights into inputs for policy design and collaborating with practitioners to learn from the process of implementation. 

Research Spotlight

how can research help in fostering economic growth

The Economic Tale of Two Amazons

This new paper synthesizes the findings of two Growth Lab projects that studied the nature of economic growth in the Peruvian and Colombian Amazon. While deforestation is often treated as inevitable to serve human needs, local and global, our research fails to find evidence of a tradeoff between economic growth and forest protection. The economic drivers in the Amazon are its urban areas often located far from the forest.

Read the Paper

People walking through a marketplace near the border of US and Mexico

The Impact of Return Migration on Employment and Wages in Mexican Cities

How does return migration affect local workers in Mexico? While migrants returning from the U.S. increase the local labor supply, they also return with new skills and knowhow, having been exposed to a more advanced U.S. economy. New research by Ricardo Hausmann and others, recently published in the Journal of Urban Economics , finds that returnees create jobs by inducing growth in the industries that hire them. 

Read article    Explore our migration research

A collage of graphs

Top Visual Insights of 2023

Our multi-disciplinary team extended our pioneering research agenda to five continents in 2023. Our researchers engaged the world in leveraging decarbonization as a pathway for growth, identifying the barriers to migration and mobility of skills, examining inequality in cities and the effects of remoteness on growth, and understanding the role of innovation in economic complexity.

Suggestions or feedback?

MIT News | Massachusetts Institute of Technology

  • Machine learning
  • Social justice
  • Black holes
  • Classes and programs

Departments

  • Aeronautics and Astronautics
  • Brain and Cognitive Sciences
  • Architecture
  • Political Science
  • Mechanical Engineering

Centers, Labs, & Programs

  • Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab (J-PAL)
  • Picower Institute for Learning and Memory
  • Lincoln Laboratory
  • School of Architecture + Planning
  • School of Engineering
  • School of Humanities, Arts, and Social Sciences
  • Sloan School of Management
  • School of Science
  • MIT Schwarzman College of Computing

Study: Democracy fosters economic growth

Press contact :, media download.

Daron Acemoglu

*Terms of Use:

Images for download on the MIT News office website are made available to non-commercial entities, press and the general public under a Creative Commons Attribution Non-Commercial No Derivatives license . You may not alter the images provided, other than to crop them to size. A credit line must be used when reproducing images; if one is not provided below, credit the images to "MIT."

Daron Acemoglu

Previous image Next image

As long as democracy has existed, there have been democracy skeptics — from Plato warning of mass rule to contemporary critics claiming authoritarian regimes can fast-track economic programs.

But a new study co-authored by an MIT economist shows that when it comes to growth, democracy significantly increases development. Indeed, countries switching to democratic rule experience a 20 percent increase in GDP over a 25-year period, compared to what would have happened had they remained authoritarian states, the researchers report. 

“I don’t find it surprising that it should be a big effect, because this is a big event, and nondemocracies, dictatorships, are messed up in many dimensions,” says Daron Acemoglu, an MIT economist and co-author of the new paper about the study.

Overall, Acemoglu notes, democracies employ broad-based investment, especially in health and human capital, which is lacking in authoritarian states. 

“Many reforms that are growth-enhancing get rid of special favors that nondemocratic regimes have done for their cronies. Democracies are much more pro-reform,” he says.

The paper, “Democracy Does Cause Growth,” is published this month in the Journal of Political Economy . The co-authors are Acemoglu, who is the Elizabeth and James Killian Professor of Economics at MIT; Suresh Naidu, an associate professor of economics and international and public affairs at Columbia University; Pascual Restrepo, an assistant professor of economics at Boston University; and James Robinson, a political scientist and economist at the Harris School of Public Policy of the University of Chicago.

Study the “switchers”

Acemoglu and Robinson have worked together for nearly two decades on research involving the interplay of institutions, political systems, and economic growth. The current paper is one product of that research program.

To conduct the study, the researchers examined 184 countries in the period from 1960 to 2010. During that time, there were 122 democratizations of countries, as well as 71 cases in which countries moved from democracy to a nondemocratic type of government.

The study focuses precisely on cases where countries have switched forms of rule. That’s because, in part, simply evaluating growth rates in democracies and nondemocracies at any one time does not yield useful comparisons. China may have grown more rapidly than France in recent decades, Acemoglu notes, but “France is a developed economy and China started at 1/20 the income per capita of France,” among many other differences.

Instead, Acemoglu and his colleagues aimed to “ask more squarely the counterfactual question” of how a country would have done with another form of government. To properly address that, he adds, “The obvious thing to do is focus on switchers” — that is, the countries changing from one mode of government to another. By closely tracking the growth trajectories of national economies in those circumstances, the researchers arrived at their conclusion.

They also found that countries that have democratized within the last 60 years have generally done so not at random moments, but at times of economic distress. That sheds light on the growth trajectories of democracies: They start off slowly while trying to rebound from economic misery. 

“Dictatorships collapse when they’re having economic problems,” Acemoglu says. “But now think about what that implies. It implies that you have a deep recession just before democratization, and you’re still going to have low GDP per capita for several years thereafter, because you’re trying to recover from this deep dive. So you’re going to see several years of low GDP during democracy.”

When that larger history is accounted for, Acemoglu says, “What we find is that [economies of democracies] slowly start picking up. So, in five or six years’ time they’re not appreciably richer than nondemocracies, but in a 10-to-15-year time horizon they become a little bit richer, and then by the end of 25 years, they are about 20 percent richer.”

Investing in people

As for the underlying mechanisms at work in the improved economies of democracies, Acemoglu notes that democratic governments tend to tax and invest more than authoritarian regimes do, particularly in medical care and education.

“Democracies … do a lot of things with their money, but two we can see are very robust are health and education,” Acemoglu says. The empirical data about those trends appear in a 2014 paper by the same four authors, “Democracy, Redistribution, and Inequality.”

For his part, Acemoglu emphasizes that the results include countries that have democratized but failed to enact much economic reform.

“That’s what’s remarkable about this result, by the way,” says Acemoglu. “There are some real basket-case democracies in our sample. … But despite that, I would say, the result is there.”

And despite the apparently sunny results of the paper, Acemoglu warns that there are no guarantees regarding a country’s political future. Democratic reforms do not help everyone in a society, and some people may prefer to let democracy wither for their own financial or political gain.

“It is possible to see this paper as an optimistic, good-news story [in which democracy] is a win-win,” says Acemoglu. “My reading is not a good-news story. … This paper is making the case that democracy is good for economic growth, but that doesn’t make it easy to sustain.” 

In the study’s sample of countries, Acemoglu adds, “We have almost twice as many democratizations as reversals of democracy, but the last 10 years, that number’s going the other way around. So democracy doesn’t have a walk in the park. It’s important to understand what democracy’s benefits are and where its fault lines are. I see this as part of that effort.”

Support for the research was provided by the Bradley Foundation and the Army Research Office Multidisciplinary University Research Initiative.

Share this news article on:

Related links.

  • Daron Acemoglu
  • Department of Economics

Related Topics

  • School of Humanities Arts and Social Sciences
  • Social sciences
  • Development
  • Developing countries
  • Political science

Related Articles

Speakers at the Feb. 26 Starr Forum, "Is Democracy Dying?"  Left to right: Melissa Nobles, Daron Acemoglu, Maria Ramirez, and Yascha Mounk.

Is democracy dying?

how can research help in fostering economic growth

Street signs

Left to right: Rich Nielsen, Charles Stewart, and Daron Acemoglu

Three MIT scholars awarded prestigious Carnegie fellowships

how can research help in fostering economic growth

State of growth

Daron Acemoglu

All the difference in the world

Previous item Next item

More MIT News

A man moves three large boxes on a handtruck while a woman standing in back of an open van takes inventory

3 Questions: Enhancing last-mile logistics with machine learning

Read full story →

Four women sit on a stage, one with a raised fist, in front of a projected slide headlined "Women in STEM."

Women in STEM — A celebration of excellence and curiosity

Stylized drawing of a computer monitor with a black screen, surrounded by green beams of light and a completed task list on each side. Behind these objects are two IBM quantum computers, shown as cylinders connected to wires

A blueprint for making quantum computers easier to program

A diagram shows a box of rows of long silver tubes stacked on top of each other. Tiny brown objects representing carbon nanotubes are in between the layers. An inset enlarges the brown objects and they are an array of tree-like scaffolding.

“Nanostitches” enable lighter and tougher composite materials

Mark Harnett stands with arms crossed in a dark lab lit with red lighting.

From neurons to learning and memory

Headshot of a woman in a colorful striped dress.

A biomedical engineer pivots from human movement to women’s health

  • More news on MIT News homepage →

Massachusetts Institute of Technology 77 Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge, MA, USA

  • Map (opens in new window)
  • Events (opens in new window)
  • People (opens in new window)
  • Careers (opens in new window)
  • Accessibility
  • Social Media Hub
  • MIT on Facebook
  • MIT on YouTube
  • MIT on Instagram
  • Browse All Articles
  • Newsletter Sign-Up

EconomicGrowth →

No results found in working knowledge.

  • Were any results found in one of the other content buckets on the left?
  • Try removing some search filters.
  • Use different search filters.

U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

The .gov means it’s official. Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

The site is secure. The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

  • Publications
  • Account settings

Preview improvements coming to the PMC website in October 2024. Learn More or Try it out now .

  • Advanced Search
  • Journal List

Logo of plosone

New insights into the impact of financial inclusion on economic growth: A global perspective

Mohammad Naim Azimi

Faculty of Economics, Kabul University, Kabul, Afghanistan

Associated Data

The datasets for GDP growth, credit to the private sector, age dependency ratio, inflation rate, school enrollment rate, population growth rate, and trade openness (total imports of goods and services plus total exports of goods and services) are collected from the World Development Indicators that are available at ( https://databank.worldbank.org/source/world-development-indicators ). Datasets for the indicators of banking penetration, availability, and usage of financial services are collected from IMF’s Financial Access Survey available at ( https://data.imf.org/?sk=E5DCAB7E-A5CA-4892-A6EA-598B5463A34C ). Dataset for the rule of law is collected from the World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators available at ( https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/ ). All datasets are publicly available for replications by scholars.

Financial inclusion is critical to inclusive growth, proffering policy solutions to eradicate the barriers that exclude individuals from financial markets. This study explores the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth in a global perspective with a large number of panels classified by income and regional levels from 2002–2020. The analysis begins with the development of a comprehensive composite financial inclusion index comprised of penetration, availability, and usage of financial services and the estimation of heterogeneous panel data models augmented with well-known variables. The results obtained from the panel cointegration test support a long-run relationship between economic growth, financial inclusion, and the control variables in the full panel, income-level, and regional-level economies. Furthermore, the study employs a GMM (generalized method of moment) approach using System-GMM estimators to examine the effects of financial inclusion and the control predictors on economic growth. The results of the GMM model clearly indicate that financial inclusion has a significantly positive impact on economic growth across all panels, implying that financial inclusion is an effective tool in fostering rapid economic growth in the world. Finally, the study delves into the causality relationship between the predictors and provides statistical evidence of bidirectional causality between economic growth and financial inclusion, whereas it only supports unidirectional causality relationships from credit to the private sector, foreign direct investment, inflation rate, the rule of law, school enrollment ratio, and trade openness with no feedback causality. Moreover, the study fails to provide causality evidence from the age dependency ratio and population to economic growth.

1. Introduction

Financial inclusion is one of the growing research topics that has recently gained popularity in the literature and received considerable attention from scholars, academics, and policymakers alike. However, the theory of financial inclusion emerged during the 1930s (see, inter alia , [ 1 ]), but the root of a wide-ranging empirical literature dates back to the early 2000s [ 2 , 3 ]. Besides, since the spark of the millennium development goals by the United Nations, the policy orientation of the financial inclusion nexus with socioeconomic indicators, specifically economic growth, among all others, has gained prominence in the formulation and implementation of strategies for sustainable development regardless of the social and economic structure of the countries. The multi-dimensionality and non-uniformity of financial inclusion outreach [ 4 ] is assumed to foster economic growth through the gradual integration of people into a formal financial system by making financial services affordable and available at a reasonable cost, and, thus, it effects are highly pronounced vis-à-vis other growth drivers [ 5 ]. Although financial inclusion is observed as an effective instrument of social inclusion in satisfying the economic desires of poor and financially excluded individuals directly, it combats extreme poverty, reduces income inequality, and encourages human capital creativity indirectly, which, in turn, has a significant impact on the economic growth of a country. In this regard, perhaps, each jurisdiction requires contextual approaches translated into formal policy frameworks to facilitate an effective and extensive outreach of financial inclusion both for included and excluded segments of society to achieve a higher rate of economic growth in the long run [ 6 ]. However, financial inclusion-driven growth takes longer than general theoretical expectations, but the development of its policy framework must articulate three key principles: affordability and undue availability of financial services for all segments of society on the supply side; financial literacy and extensive accessibility on the demand side; and consumer protection, accountability, and institutional quality on the governance side [ 7 ].

In recognition of the importance of financial inclusion on economic growth, however, most of the recent studies have departed from the foundational theory of financial inclusion and dived either into endogenous or exogenous models. But regardless of the methodology and magnitude of the effects presented, the available empirical literature has taken three main directions. The first group of studies have examined the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth and other socioeconomic predictors in country-specific contexts with limited outcome generalizability (see, for instance, [ 8 – 14 ]). The second group of studies on financial inclusion impact has focused on specific regional classifications, such as Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA), Asia’s developing economies, the One Belt One Road Initiative (OBRI), the Organization for Islamic Cooperation (OIC), and the South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation (SAARC) member countries (see, inter alia , [ 15 – 19 ]). The third group of empirical studies has focused either on the panels of mixed economies or developed and developing economies (see, for example, [ 20 – 25 ]).

Although an exception is given to empirical studies by Okonkwo and Ifeanyi [ 26 ] in low and middle-income countries; Van and Linh [ 27 ] in East Asia and the Pacific region; Emara and Mohieldin [ 28 ] in the Middle-East and North Africa (MENA); and Ghassibe et al. [ 29 ] in the Middle-East and Central Asia, the existing literature reports the non-existence of a comprehensive empirical study to have examined the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth from a global perspective to provide both statistical evidence on the scale of effects and comparative results by region and income-level economies to support extensive policy formulation. Therefore, it is imperative to direct the study by formulating three important questions. First, does financial inclusion have positive effects on economic growth in global, regional, and income-level economies, though some recent empirical studies provide counter-evidence? Second, are the effects of financial inclusion non-monotonic and vary across panels (global, regional, and income-level) due to economic size as represented by GDP growth? Third, are there any causality relationships between financial inclusion and economic growth with a feedback response?

The present study is an attempt to delve into the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth by controlling for major macroeconomic predictors from global, income-level, and regional-level perspectives. As an empirical fact, the literature is still evolving to understand the magnitude, extent, and direction of the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth—an emerging paradox—and the number of studies that have focused on country-specific, developed, and developing economies with mixed and even confounded results is not sufficient to support a global agenda on the subject. Moreover, the scarcity of a comprehensive empirical study highlighting the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth from a global perspective to facilitate extensive policy comparison is a significant missing gap in the literature and forms the key motivation for the present study.

The remaining sections of the study are structured as follows. Section two presents a review of literature discussing both theoretical and empirical concepts of financial inclusion and growth. Section three presents the data, variables, and construction methodology of the composite financial inclusion index. Section four develops the theoretical model of the study. Section five explains the estimation strategy of the panel data. Section six presents the results and discusses the findings. Section seven concludes the study.

2. Literature review

2.1 theoretical background.

The existing literature on the finance-growth nexus owes to Schumpeter’s [ 1 ] initial theory, stating that financial intermediaries are essential to advance technical innovations in businesses to ensure stable economic growth through saving mobilization, project evaluation, risk analysis, transaction, and money circulation conduits [ 30 ]. The theory predicts that missed opportunities are caused by inactive assets held both at personal and organizational disposal due to the absence of financial intermediaries to mobilize savings and enlarge money circulation. This, in turn, forces people to rely on wage-based savings and limits money circulation through financially profitable conduits. On the other hand, market imperfection insulates poor citizens from eluding poverty through limitation of access to formal financial products [ 15 ], whereas wider access to financial services has been excoriated as one of the most useful tactics for combating poverty, owing to the fact that higher levels of financial inclusion are linked to lower levels of income inequality and higher economic growth [ 31 ]. Since then, scholars have attempted to build various theoretical models to capture the notion of growth around the concept of Schumpeter and have provided many definitions to describe financial services (see, inter alia , [ 32 – 35 ]). Among all others, Sarma [ 36 ] has provided a comprehensive definition for the notion of financial services—that is, "financial inclusion" as a set of formal financial services to bankable individuals and the process through which such services are made available, accessible, and usable at reasonable economic cost. Thus, in line with this definition, financial inclusion can be regarded as one of the key drivers of economic growth through an increase in general consumption, higher profitable investments, a reduction in monetary overhang by the availability of financial services, and a shift from wage-based savings to return on investments [ 37 ]. Therefore, it entails two main principles that postulate the theory of financial inclusion. First, the beneficiary theory of financial inclusion, which comprises vulnerable group theory, dissatisfaction theory, and public good theory; and second, the theory of delivery of financial inclusion, comprising public money theory, echelon theory, and private money theory [ 38 ]. Thus, the latter—that is, the theory of delivery of financial inclusion—forms the theoretical direction of the present study. However, far from the basic theory of financial inclusion, almost all recent studies have considered either endogenous or exogenous growth models.

2.2 Measurement of financial inclusion

Although based on the multi-faceted theory of financial inclusion, there are numerous definitions that have a general consensus on the outreach of financial inclusion to provide excessive financial services to the bankable members of a nation, prioritizing the gradual integration of the excluded people into the formal financial system of an economy. Thus, giving rise to the conceptual importance, a comprehensive tool is essential to measure the impact of financial inclusion on various socioeconomic indicators. Despite other quasi-mechanisms (see, inter alia , [ 10 , 38 – 40 ]), this study follows Sarma [ 41 ], who enhanced the construction methodology of the composite financial inclusion index using a distance-based approach dissimilar to the human development index adopted by the United Nations Development Programs (UNDP), using average dimension indexes. A three-dimensional approach to construct the composite financial inclusion index is the banking penetration, availability, and usage of financial services, which are defined as follows.

Banking penetration—that is, access to financial services—indicates the number of users of financial services in an economy, measured by the number of deposit accounts per 1,000 adults and the number of depositors per 1,000 adults [ 41 – 43 ]. Here, the first indicator reflects the size of the bankable segment of society, while the second indicator shows the total number of banked individuals, comprising both active and non-active account holders with financial institutions [ 44 , 45 ]. Next is the availability dimension, which comprises two key indicators, such as the number of banks per 100,000 adults and the number of automated teller machines (ATMs) per 100,000 adults. It reflects the geographical availability of financial services in terms of banking outlets, bank branches, and the ATMs that are available for utilization [ 40 , 46 ]. Third is the usage dimension, which also comprises two key indicators, such as the number of loan accounts in banks per 1,000 people and the number of borrowers from banks per 1,000 adults. This dimension measures how customers use financial services in the form of transfers, remittances, borrowing, and savings to reflect the efficiency and inclusiveness of the financial services that are available to people in an economy [ 35 , 47 ].

2.3 Review of recent studies

Although the existing literature still evolves in presenting a sufficient number of empirical works on the effects of financial inclusion on various socioeconomic indicators to encourage comprehensive macroeconomic policy attempts (see, for instance, [ 48 , 49 ]), it owes its first study to Marc et al. [ 50 ], who claimed to have found statistical relationships between financial structure and economic growth. For brevity, this section reviews the most recent studies about the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth in different geographical contexts. For instance, Estrada et al. [ 51 ] examined the effects of financial systems, banks, and equity markets on economic growth in 125 developing countries. The authors have used simple methods and found that the financial system’s outreach postulates significant effects on economic growth, though the results might be confounded due to misspecification and the choice of financial inclusion predictors. Kpodar and Andrianaivo [ 52 ] evaluated the effects of information and communication technologies, mobile phone rollout, and the number of deposits per head—that is, the predictors of financial inclusion—on economic growth in a sample of African economies from 1988–2007. The authors employed the system generalized method of moment technique to overcome any endogeneity issue and found that financial inclusion is an effective tool to increase economic growth in the context of Africa.

Masoud and Hardaker [ 53 ] employed an endogenous growth model and a set of data for twelve years to examine the effects of stock market development and the banking sector on economic growth in forty-two emerging economies. The authors found that the stock market has a significant influence on the economic growth of the emerging markets and that they move together in the long run. Moreover, they argue that the banking sector is complementary to the stock market in easing customers’ access to their desired financial services. Lenka and Sharma [ 54 ] examined the effect of financial inclusion (penetration, access, and usage dimension) on economic growth in India. The authors used a set of time-series data from 1980–2014, a principal component analysis method to construct the financial inclusion index and the autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) and error-correction methods to estimate the short and long-run effects of financial inclusion on growth. The authors found that financial inclusion has a positive effect on economic growth both in the short and long runs. Moreover, they also provided evidence of a unidirectional relationship between financial inclusion and economic growth.

Le et al. [ 55 ] tested the linkage between financial inclusion, growth, and other socioeconomic indicators in 20 Asian economies from 2011–2016 using a random effects model for panel data analysis. The authors found that Asian countries with a higher growth rate have higher financial inclusion to channelize higher economic growth; an inverse association between financial inclusion and unemployment rate; and the role of financial literacy in effectively utilizing the available financial services. Erlando et al. [ 56 ] examined the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth using a set of panel data for Eastern Indonesia. The authors employed the modified vector autoregressive method of Toda and Yamamoto, bivariate causality, and dynamic panel vector autoregressive methods. They found a statistically strong nexus between financial inclusion and economic growth, noticing that financial inclusion spurs economic. On the other hand, Nizam et al. [ 57 ] analyzed the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth in 63 developed and developing countries over the period from 2014–2017 using threshold regression analysis. The authors found that there is a threshold effect of financial inclusion on economic growth, implying that the effects are positive but are translated at a higher level than in the low level of the financial inclusion index.

Moreover, the existing literature indicates a counter-example about the negative effects of financial inclusion on economic growth by Rodríguez et al. [ 58 ]; who analyzed the relationships between them in 71 countries using a set of data spanning from 2007–2016; and applied ordinary least squares, the generalized method of moment with two-way fixed effects, and Granger causality methods to test their developed hypotheses. They found a negative association between financial inclusion and economic growth, highlighting that financial inclusion exerts an adverse effect on growth and a statistically significant causality nexus between them. Meanwhile, Shen et al. [ 59 ] used datasets from the WDI (World Development Indicators) and the IMF (International Monetary Funds) to examine the effects of financial inclusion index on economic growth in 105 countries. The authors used spatial data techniques to analyze the relationships between digital financial inclusion, growth, and other control variables and found that digital financial inclusion has a significantly positive impact on the economic growth of the countries.

Finally, Ozturk and Sana [ 60 ] examined the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth and environmental quality in forty-two countries linked with the One Belt One Road Initiative (OBRI) using a set of data spanning from 2007–2019. The authors employed pooled ordinary least squares (OLS), two-stage OLS, and the generalized method of moment (GMM) models. They found that financial inclusion has a positive impact on economic growth but has negative effects on environmental quality through the flow of CO2 emissions.

The purview of the existing literature reveals that the empirical studies conducted to examine the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth have left two significant gaps. First, it reports no comprehensive study to reflect the impact of financial inclusion on growth from a global perspective and no comparative results for cross-country groupings by income and regional levels using unified analytical methodology to highlight comprehensive policy implications to support the literal arguments of the paradigm shift—that is, a shift from financial development to financial inclusion as a global agenda. Second, the mixed and confounded results presented by the existing literature have enhanced the paradox of the effects of financial inclusion as a driver of growth. Therefore, to fill these gaps, it is important to formulate three key hypotheses. H 1 : As claimed by the initial concept, financial inclusion has a positive impact on economic growth regardless of economic size and structure across the globe. H 2 : Though the effects are positive on growth, they are non-monotonic and specified by the size of the economies, viz-à-viz, the GDP. H 3 : While financial inclusion explains economic growth, it is strongly affected by the growth rate of an economy—that is, there is a bidirectional link between them.

3. Data and variables

The datasets contain 218 countries across the world, employing annual observations spanning from 2004–2021 compiled from reliable sources and are organized by various panels reflecting income and regional level economies reported by the World Bank classification report [ 61 ]. The variables used are consistent with recent empirical literature and include GDP growth, the composite financial inclusion index, school enrollment rate, age dependency ratio, credit to the private sector, the rule of law, inflation rate, trade openness, the Gini index, and population growth rate. Table 1 provides complete information about them. The study employs GDP growth as the dependent variable proxied for economic growth and the composite financial inclusion index as the independent and key variable of interest. However, the construction method of the composite financial inclusion index (CFII) is discussed later; the present study controls for several macroeconomic predictors to avoid any omitted variable bias. Thus, the school enrollment ratio (SER) is used as a proxy for human capital development. Intuitively, an increase in school enrollment increases skills, knowledge, and creativity, thereby stimulating economic growth. Moreover, the age dependency ratio is used to control its effects on growth. Theory predicts that either too young or too old citizens would be cost-burdensome and negatively impact the growth. Credit to the private sector may also influence economic progression, viz-à-viz greater access to credit facilitates higher capital investment, thus spurring economic growth. Studies by Le et al. [ 55 ], Sayed and Shusha [ 43 ], and Rashdan and Eissa [ 45 ] suggest including the inflation rate as a control variable when delving into the effects of CFII on growth. It is important to understand the effects of higher inflationary episodes that cause the saving rates to decrease and suppress the citizens’ use of desired financial services. In light of the globalized economy, it is essential to augment the trade openness in the model to measures the cross-country access of financial services by traders. Despite controlling for the income inequality proxied by Gini index, the study also controls for the effects of institutional quality proxied by the rule of law. It is widely documented that the rule of law is an appropriate proxy for institutional quality when analyzing the effects of CFII on growth [ 62 ]. Finally, population growth rate is also used to control its effects on economic growth.

Notes: The Gini index compiled from SWIID is constructed by Solt [ 63 ]. WDI = World Development Indicators, FAS = Financial Access Survey, WGI = Worldwide Governance Indicators, SWIID = Standard World Income Inequality Database.

Unlike recent empirical studies that followed the construction methodology of the composite index explained by UNDP for HDI (Human Development Index), the present article adopts a more comprehensive method proposed by Sarma [ 41 ] to construct the CFII. Literally, financial inclusion outreach is based on three key dimensions, such as banking penetration, the availability, and the usage of financial services by the bankable population. To quantify, each dimension comprises two key indicators, and thereby, each indicator is assigned an appropriate numerical weight (see Table A1 of Appendix A in S1 Appendix ). The construction begins with the specification of dimension index observing minimum and maximum integers using d i = w i ( A ik , t − m i / M i − m i ), in which, d , w i , A i , m i , and M i present the normalized integer, weight, actual value of the country k in time t , lower limit (fixed by value 0), and upper limit (fixed by 90 th percentile rank) of the dimension i , respectively [ 64 ]. Considering this, the CFII is estimated using the notions of distance ( d ) achievements of points ( d 1 , d 2 , d 3 ,…, d n ) from ( O = 0, 0, 0,…, 0) being the worst point and from ( W = w 1 , w 2 , w 3 ,…, w n ) being an ideal point as:

where Eq (1) is used to estimate the normalized Euclidian distance between the achievement point ( x ) and worst position ( O ) on the n th space [ 65 ]. Then, to estimate the normalized inverse distance between ( x ) and ideal position ( W ) on the n th space, the following equation is employed:

Finally, to estimate the CFII, the average of Eqs ( 1 ) and ( 2 ) are taken as:

This method of CFII construction is widely used in financial econometrics as a standardized predictor of comprehensive financial inclusion index (see, for instance, [ 43 , 46 , 66 ]).

4. Model specification

To obtain specification for delving into the effects of composite financial inclusion index on economic growth, this study draws on Kim et al. [ 15 ] and Andiansyah [ 67 ] and begins with a long-run panel specification as:

where φ = intercept, η 1 − η 9 = long-run panel coefficients, t = 1, 2, …, = T , i = 1, 2, …, = N , u = error term of the model following identically and independently normal distribution ( i . i . n . d .) assumption, and all other variables hold the same meaning as explained before. Except for the rule of law, which is augmented to control for institutional quality on growth, the choice of other explanatory variables is based on recent empirical studies (see, inter alia , [ 27 , 67 – 70 ]). Moreover, it is expected that the signs of η 1 , η 2 , η 4 , and η 7 > 0, the signs of η 3 , η 6 , and η 9 < 0 and the sign of η 5 to be a-priori indeterminate; that is, based on the advancement of institutional quality in high-income and upper middle-income economies, it may show positive effects on growth, whilst a negative sign is expected in low-income economies due to deteriorating institutional quality.

5. Econometric methods

5.1 cointegration test.

From the reviewed literature and recent empirical studies on applied panel data techniques, the present study avoids testing the unit root of the predictors, considering the empirical fact that the number of units is greater than the observations in a panel [ 71 – 74 ]. Therefore, it dives into testing for the panel cointegration to establish the long-run nexus amid indicators. For the rejected null of cross-sectional independence in the panel, the use of common panel cointegration tests such as Kao [ 75 ] and Pedroni [ 76 ] may lead to biased results. Thus, the study employs the panel LM (Lagrange Multiplier) bootstrap cointegration test proposed by Westerlund and Edgerton [ 77 ], which allows for cross-sectional dependence and produces accurate results in small samples. It follows the same principal component analysis explained by Westerlund [ 78 ] and is initiated as:

where t = 1,…, T , i = 1, …, N and x it = x it −1 + v it exhibiting I(1) series presenting the K-dimensional regressor vector, D it presents the break dummy, F ^ t is the common factor, and λ ^ i is the factor loading for principal component analysis. Therefore, with the help of Eq (6) given below, the panel LM test statistics is computed as:

where φ , the change sign Δ, and ε are the intercept, first difference operator, and the error term of the model, respectively. Using the LM bootstrap, the null hypothesis indicates panel cointegration, given that the bootstrap ( p > 0.05) for the LM test statistics against its alternative of no cointegration for all cross-sections.

5.2 GMM approach

To estimate Eq (4) , and considering the properties of the panel data used in this study, whether cointegrated or not, it employs the generalized method of moment (GMM), which is an appropriate econometric approach suitable for the case of this study. The choice of using the GMM technique is based on empirical facts—the existence of cross-sectional dependence among country groupings, panel endogeneity, and the low frequency of observations compared to the number of units in the panel, say, T < N [ 79 ]. For brevity, considering a linear regression with endogenous regressors, this study initiates building the GMM model as:

where y it = the dependent variable, say, economic growth; u it = N × 1 vectors, ϑ = K × 1 vector for the unknown parameters, x it = N × K matrix for the explanatory variables, and u it is the error term of the model. Assuming that there is an endogeneity issue in the panel, it considers a matrix x it with N × L given that L > K , where z it matrix comprises a set of predictors that are strongly correlated with x it but have orthogonality with u it , say, they are not highly correlated with the error term. Thus, z it is assumed to be exogeneous following E ( z i t ′ u i t ) = 0 assumption [ 80 ]. For GMM estimation, there are two approaches, such as System GMM (Sys-GMM) and Difference GMM (Diff-GMM). For the Sys-GMM, the employed equation takes the following form:

where ln = natural log of the predictors, φ = coefficient of the lagged dependent variable, and ϑ = coefficient of the lagged explanatory variables, and other vector predictors hold the same meaning as explained before. Eq (8) is a level equation comprising fixed effects, while Diff-GMM transforms the predictors by first differencing to remove the fixed effects as:

where Δ u it = Δ η i + Δ ε it , say, u it − u it −1 = ( η i − η i ) + (Δ ε it − Δ ε it −1 ), and other variables hold the same meaning as explained before. Now, Eq (9) removes the fixed effects and does not vary along with the time, but the problem of panel endogeneity still remains. Moreover, Δ ln y it , which is the first-differenced lagged dependent variable is instrumented with its lagged value and its changes are shown by Eq (9) . According to Blundell and Bond [ 80 ], if the dependent variable is a random walk process, Eq (9) may produce biased and inconsistent estimate of φ in finite samples, especially when the time period is short, which is attributed to poor instruments in the model. To that end, preference is given to Sys-GMM estimation as it simultaneously computes two equations. One with a level, and the instruments in first differenced form. Second, with the first difference, the instruments are expressed in the level form. This method includes more moment conditions when the time period is short and the dependent variable is assumed to be a random walk. Therefore, it gains precision and small sample distortion is reduced. The Sys-GMM estimation is based on two approaches, such as 1Sys-GMM (one step system GMM) and 2Sys-GMM (two step system GMM), where the former assumes no heteroskedasticity and serial correlation and the latter corrects them by exploiting a weighting matrix based on the residuals from the 1Sys-GMM.

Moreover, GMM estimation has several empirical advantages over the common techniques for panel data analysis. First, it controls for omitted variable bias, correlation between the variables, and any potential measurement errors. Second, it produces consistent and accurate results of the coefficients for panel samples with N > T. Third, it corrects the unobserved endogeneity by transforming the regressors through differencing and removing the fixed effects. Fourth, in terms of heteroskedasticity and serial correlation, the Sys-GMM, which is an augmentation of the Diff-GMM, is more consistent, robust, and efficient.

As suggested by the existing literature, in this study, the analysis begins with the estimation of Eq (4) by pooled ordinary least squares (OLS) and the least squares dummy variable (LSDV) using fixed effects methods. Doing so leads the study to select an appropriate GMM estimator and avoid misspecification. Therefore, the pooled OLS panel estimate for φ is used as an upper bound, while the fixed effect estimates are used as the lower bounds. If the Diff-GMM estimates are close to or below the fixed effects estimates, Sys-GMM is more consistent and efficient as Diff-GMM would be biased due to weak instrumentation. Moreover, it is also important to test for instruments validity, for which Hansen’s [ 81 ] J-statistics and Sargan’s [ 82 ] methods are employed to test the validity of the instrumental variables augmented in the GMM model. Rejecting the null hypothesis implies that the instruments are invalid [ 83 ], while failing to reject the null implies otherwise. Furthermore, this study tests the null of no second-order serial correlation in the error term using the Arellano and Bond [ 79 ] method. Failing to reject the null implies that no second-order serial correlation exists and that the moment conditions are appropriately specified.

5.3 Panel causality test

Finally, this study delves into the causal relationships between economic growth and the composite financial inclusion and employs the proposed model of Dumitrescu and Hurlin [ 84 ] causality test for heterogeneous panel. This test is suitable for the panels that exhibit cross-sectional dependence and when T < N, as in this case. Thus, it provides more consistent results than other common methods. The equation used to test the causality between the predictors is expressed as:

where α , λ , β , and ε are the intercept, the coefficient for the lagged dependent variable, the coefficient for the lagged independent variable, and the error term of the model, respectively. Eq (10) tests the null of no causality between the predictors in the cross-sections, using individual Wald statistics for each unit and averaged Wald statistics for the whole panel (see [ 84 ], for technical details).

6. Results and discussion

6.1 descriptive statistics.

The analysis begins with some important summary statistics about the variables, reported in Table B1 of Appendix B in S2 Appendix . It shows that the mean value for GDP growth is 2.74% for the full panel, while it is 2%, 4.48%, 5.69%, 6.13%, 1.52%, 1.11%, 4.91%, 1.41%, 2.12%, 3.87%, 1.78%, 5.71%, and 3.99% for low-income, middle-income, upper middle-income, high-income, OECD, non-OECD, East Asia and the Pacific, Europe and Central Asia, Latin America and Caribbean, MENA, North America, South Asia, and Sub-Saharan African economies, respectively. On the other hand, the summary statistics indicate that the mean value for the composite financial inclusion index is 0.26, 0.78, 0.73, 0.69, 0.71, 0.82, 0.74, 0.71, 0.73, 0.68, 0.74, 0.79, 0.68, and 0.72 for the full panel, low-income, middle-income, upper middle-income, high-income, OECD, non-OECD, East Asia and the Pacific, Europe and Central Asia, Latin America and Caribbean, MENA, North America, South Asia, and Sub-Saharan African economies, respectively. It reveals that among all others, although the growth rate of the high-income countries has been the highest throughout the period, their CFII rank has relatively been lower than those of the low-income, middle-income, upper middle-income, OECD, MENA, North America, South Asia, and Sub-Saharan African countries. Moreover, another interesting indicator is the rule of law, which shows that its mean value does not necessarily correspond to the growth rate and the mean value of the financial inclusion outreach. For instance, the mean value of the rule of law is 90.33 percentile rank for high-income economies, which is the highest among all others, while its growth rate and CFII average rate are reported otherwise. For brevity, one can read through the variations among the predictors, but the study proceeds to delve into the cointegration among them.

6.2 Cointegration analysis

To ascertain the long-run nexus amid predictors, the Westerlund and Edgerton [ 77 ] cointegration test by LM bootstraps was computed, and the results are shown in Table 2 . For the rejected null hypothesis of no cointegration, except for the low-income economies, the findings reveal that there exists significant cointegration among the predictors in all panels. This implies that panel predictors move together in the long run—that is, the composite financial inclusion index, which is the key variable of interest, and other explanatory variables postulate significant effects on economic growth and cannot be deviated from long-run equilibrium. The results are consistent with the findings of Nwanne [ 85 ], Hassan [ 86 ], Ratnawati [ 87 ], and Ain et al. [ 88 ], who also established statistical long-run relationships between financial inclusion and economic growth. Moreover, the results satisfy the underlying theory of growth-financial inclusion [ 14 ], implying that excessive financial inclusion outreach facilitates higher capital mobility and integration of a higher proportion of unbanked individuals into the formal financial system, which leads to higher economic growth in the long run.

***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. () indicates Z-values. The corresponding p-values are robust and are performed under 100 bootstraps replications.

6.3 GMM estimates

As for the key results of interest, Tables ​ Tables3 3 and ​ and4 4 report the results of robust GMM estimation—that is, 1Sys-GMM, 2Sys-GMM, and Diff-GMM for the full panel, income level groupings, and regional economies. As discussed earlier, using empirical diagnostics, the Sys-GMM estimators are preferred over the Diff-GMM, and thus, the interpretation of the results and discussion of findings are based on the 2Sys-GMM results, though the results of the 1Sys-GMM are similar to those of the 2Sys-GMM. For robustness, it follows the Windmeijer [ 89 ] correction in the standard errors of the 2Sys-GMM estimation to control for the downward biasedness of standard errors, controlling the instrument matrix, observation weight, the difference-in-Sargan/Hansen test of instrument validity, and the forward orthogonal transform, which is an alternative to the differencing approach of Arellano and Bover [ 90 ], preserving sample size in panels with observational gaps.

***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. [] indicates test statistics.

For simplicity and use of limited space, the results of the pooled OLS and LSDV fixed effects models are omitted from the present study and will be available upon request. Moreover, to simplify reading through the results and to highlight significant findings, the study reports the results by income and regional classifications as shown in Tables ​ Tables3 3 and ​ and4 4 .

6.3.1 Full panel

The results of the full panel, thereby the world panel, reflect the overall effects of financial inclusion—a key variable of interest—and other explanatory predictors on economic growth, consisting of (218) countries. The results indicate that financial inclusion proxied by CFII (composite financial inclusion index) has a significantly positive impact on the world’s economic growth, implying that one percent increase in financial inclusion (penetration, availability, and usage of financial services) increases the world’s economic growth by 0.316%, ceteris-paribus. The results are consistent with the theoretical expectations about the positive growth-financial inclusion nexus and empirical findings of Kim et al. [ 15 ] for 55 member countries of the OIC (Organization of Islamic Cooperation), Siddik et al. [ 19 ] for 24 Asian developing economies, Singh and Stakic [ 18 ] for 8 SAARC (South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation) member countries, and Huang et al. [ 17 ] for 27 countries of the European Union. Though, for brevity, other explanatory variables, such as age dependency ratio (–), inflation rate (–), foreign direct investment (+), school enrollment ratio (+), trade openness (+), and population growth (–) have their varying expected effects on economic growth, the rule of law, which is augmented in the model to ascertain its mediating effects on growth, shows that institutional quality is significant to ease the impact of financial inclusion on growth. For instance, the results demonstrate that a 1% increase in the percentile rank of the rule of law causes economic growth to increase by 0.321% in a global context. This is supported by recent empirical findings by Valeriani and Peluso [ 91 ], Nguyen et al. [ 68 ], Salman et al. [ 12 ], and Radulović [ 92 ], who also documented the effects of institutional quality on economic growth. Furthermore, an economic intuition suggests that higher institutional quality—that is, comprehensive rule of law—facilitates indirect economic growth through various conduits, one of which is financial inclusion outreach.

Moreover, the control variables, such as age dependency ratio, inflation rate, and population growth rate, decrease economic growth by 0.024%, 0.010%, and 0.081%, respectively. The negativity of the age dependency ratio implies the reduction of productivity in the world and a declining long-run trend in growth, whilst the negativity of the inflation rate on growth may additionally cause excessive cost-burden for bankable customers and reduce the scope of financial inclusion. Although some recent studies found that population growth has a positive impact on the economy, the current study finds that a 1% increase in population growth rate reduces economic growth by 0.081%. This is consistent with the findings of Easterlin [ 93 ], Klasen [ 11 ], and Mason and Lee [ 94 ] on the combined population projected effects on lowering economic growth by 1 percentage point per year.

6.3.2 Income-level

However, the results are statistically significant for all income-level economies, but they reveal that for low-income countries, financial inclusion has a positive impact and increases economic growth by 0.085%, while comparatively, it increases the economic growth of middle-income, upper middle-income, high-income, OECD, and non-OECD member countries by 0.119%, 0.212%, 0.419%, 0.405%, and 0.146%, respectively. This highlights an important variation in the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth, varying with respect to the income level of the countries. Considering the rule of law as a proxy for institutional quality, the results indicate that its effect also varies across income-level groupings. It shows that, ceteris paribus, one percentile rank increase in the rule of law causes economic growth by 0.112%, 0.348%, 0.417%, 0.537%, 0.642%, 0.240% in low-income, middle-income, upper middle-income, high-income, OECD, and non-OECD countries, respectively. Thus, the variation of the effects of financial inclusion may be due to two key reasons: the economic size of the countries and the implementation of the rule of law in governing, allocating, and using financial resources for the sake of rapid growth. Consistently, Azimi [ 95 ] also clearly shows that the non-monotonic effects of the rule of law are based on the varying economic size of the country. The findings indicate that the higher the income level, the greater the impact of financial inclusion on economic growth will be. Furthermore, the results show that the theoretically expected effects of the control variables, such as age dependency ratio (–), credit to the private sector (+), foreign direct investment (+), inflation rate (–), school enrollment rate (+), trade openness (+), and population growth rate (–) on the economic growth of the income-level grouping are achieved. Not surprisingly, the impact of the control variables on growth is also found to be non-monotonic.

For instance, the credit to the private sector has a significantly positive effects on growth, showing that a 1% increase in credit to the private sector, the economic growth increases by 0.130%, 0.322%, 0.332%, 0.348% in low-income, middle-income, upper middle-income, and high-income economies, respectively. Olowofeso et al. [ 24 ], Cuong [ 23 ], and Samuel-Hope et al. [ 22 ] also found statistical evidence of the positive effects of credit to the private sector on economic growth in various economic contexts. On the other hand, foreign direct investment also posits positive effects on growth. Its effect on growth is 0.514%, 0.438%, 0.502%, 0.612%, 0.441%, and 0.604% for low-income, middle-income, upper middle-income, high-income, OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development), and non-OECD member countries, respectively. Moreover, the negative association between the inflation rate and the age dependency ratio is lower in high-income but higher in low-income economies. For example, the negative effect of the inflation rate on growth is -0.382% in low-income countries, while it is -0.118%, -0.218%, and -0.117% in middle-income, upper middle-income, and high-income countries, respectively. Studies by Babajide et al. [ 96 ]; Lenka and Sharma [ 97 ]; Dahiya and Kumar [ 13 ]; and Okonkwo and Ifeanyi [ 26 ] also provide statistical evidence of the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth in low and middle-income countries. Consistently, Sethi and Acharya [ 21 ] found a significant association between growth and financial inclusion in 31 countries across the world, consisting of low, middle, and high-income economies, while Li et al. [ 20 ] extended the statistical findings of the effects of financial inclusion in OECD member countries, supporting the findings of the present study.

6.3.3 Regional-level

To facilitate better analysis and deeper insights into the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth, the present study delves into the matter using the regional classification of the countries. Comparatively, the results provide much deeper views of the growth-financial inclusion association in regional contexts. The results demonstrate that financial inclusion, which is the key variable of interest, is statistically significant at 1% level and spurs economic growth by 0.218% in East Asia and the Pacific, 0.209% in Europe and Central Asia, 0.408% in Latin America and the Caribbean, 0.501% in MENA, 0.256% in North America, 0.783% in South Asia, and 0.642% in Sub-Saharan African countries. Comparatively, the results indicate that South Asia’s growth has the highest reaction to financial inclusion among all others, while Europe and Central Asia’s growth rate has the lowest response to financial inclusion. The results are consistent with the findings of Van and Linh [ 27 ] in East Asia and the Pacific and Abdul Karim et al. [ 25 ] in sixty developed and developing economies, Adalessossi and Kaya [ 98 ] and Wokabi and Fatoki [ 99 ] in African countries, Thathsarani et al. [ 2 ] in eight South Asian countries, Gakpa [ 100 ] and Adedokun and Ağa [ 16 ] in Sub-Saharan African countries, Emara and Mohieldin [ 28 ] in MENA, and Ghassibe et al. [ 29 ] in the Middle-East and Central Asia, who also found that financial inclusion is a significant determinant of economic growth and an effective tool to facilitate greater financial integration. From a macroeconomic standpoint, increasing unbanked individuals’ access to financial services leads to increased money circulation and credit exchange in the economy, resulting in a significant impact on stable economic growth [ 101 ], whereas integrating unbanked individuals into the formal financial system results in a meaningful reduction in tax avoidance, money laundering, and transaction costs [ 57 ]. However, the proportional impact of financial inclusion is relatively lower than that of financial deepening, but it continues to encourage more unbanked populations to join the formal financial system to generate higher impacts on economic growth. For instance, in East Asia and the Pacific, the results indicate that financial inclusion significantly increases economic growth by 0.218%, while other predictors, such as credit to the private sector, foreign direct investment, the rule of law, school enrollment rate, and trade openness, also exert positive effects on growth by 1.378%, 0.783%, 0.321%, 1.032%, and 1.016%, respectively. A quick intra-comparison shows that financial deepening, human capital, and economic openness—that is, credit to the private sector, school enrollment ratio, and trade, respectively—have much higher effects on growth than financial inclusion in East Asia and the Pacific. The same results apply to all regional economies, except for South Asian countries that exhibit a different scale but similar magnitude. It is found that, in South Asia, a 1% increase in financial inclusion significantly causes economic growth to increase by 0.783%. With respect to both the inter-region and intra-region comparisons, the effects of financial inclusion on growth are higher than in other regional and income-level economies. This could be due to obvious factors such as significant advancements and support for financial inclusion in South Asia’s three most populous countries, India, Pakistan, and Bangladesh, which are constantly expanding the reach of their financial inclusion services. This finding is also supported by Thathsarani et al. [ 2 ] in eight South Asian economies, who found that the comparative effects of financial inclusion are lower than other financial development predictors on growth, and by Park and Mercado [ 102 ] in thirty-three developing economies, who provided similar findings on the comparative effects of financial inclusion on economic growth. For the control variables, the results indicate that age dependency ratio, inflation rate, and population growth are statistically significant and posit negative impacts on the economic growth of the regional economies, while credit to the private sector, foreign direct investment, school enrollment rate, and trade openness have positive associations with economic growth. Moreover, the results also show that institutional quality proxied by the rule of law has a significantly positive impact on economic growth, whereas, as theory suggests, higher institutional quality leads to efficient and effective delivery of financial services and thus paves the way for swift economic growth. The results reported in Tables ​ Tables3 3 and ​ and4 4 are statistically robust. The diagnostic checks of the relevant tests are reported at the rear part of the tables.

6.4 Causality nexus

Finally, the present study computes the panel causality test of Dumitrescu and Hurlin [ 84 ] and reports the results in Table 5 , highlighting interesting results. They reveal that there is a significant bidirectional causality relationship between economic growth and financial inclusion at a 1% level in the full panel, income-level panels, and regional panels. Since feedback responses—that is, reverse causality statistics of the control variables—have not been significant, they are not reported in Table 5 . The results indicate that except for the age dependency ratio (ADR) and population growth rate (PGR), which are insignificant in causing economic growth in the full and all other classified panels, the rest of the variables, such as credit to the private sector, foreign direct investment, inflation rate, the rule of law, school enrollment ratio, and trade openness, are significant enough to exhibit unidirectional causality to cause economic growth. The results support the findings of Sharma [ 103 ], Mlachila et al. [ 104 ], Sethi and Acharya [ 21 ] in a panel of both developed and developing countries, and Gourène and Mendy [ 105 ] in the West African Economic and Monetary Union, who also found directional causality relationships between financial inclusion and economic growth in different economic contexts. The results are in contrast with those of Asmalidar and Pratomo [ 106 ], who claimed that there is no causality nexus amid financial inclusion and economic growth.

***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. = >/ indicates the null of no panel causality relationship. [] indicates p-values .

7. Conclusion

The present study explored the effects of financial inclusion on the world’s economic growth and extended the analysis to delve into how financial inclusion influences economic growth in a number of panels classified by income-level (low, middle, upper middle, high, OECD, and non-OECD) economies and regional-level (East Asia and the Pacific, Europe and Central Asia, Latin America and the Caribbean, MENA, North America, South Asia, and Sub-Saharan Africa) economies using panel datasets spanning from 2002–2020 compiled from the World Bank’s World Development Indicators and IMF’s Financial Access Survey databases. To test the developed hypotheses, the study employed heterogeneous robust panel cointegration by bootstraps, GMM (generalized method of moment), and heterogeneous panel causality tests for two key objectives: ascertaining the scale of the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth and the causality nexus among them. First, to provide consistent results, the study used the methodology proposed by Sarma [ 41 ] and developed a comprehensive composite financial inclusion index comprised of penetration, availability, and usage of financial services for all panels under consideration. Next, the study provides statistically significant cointegration between composite financial inclusion, economic growth proxied by GDP growth, and other control variables, such as age dependency ratio, credit to the private sector, foreign direct investment, inflation rate, the rule of law, school enrollment ratio, trade openness, and population growth rate. The cointegration results support the idea that, in the long run, financial inclusion moves in tandem with economic growth, suggesting a thorough examination of their interactions. To that end, led by the nature of the data, the study employed a GMM approach using 1Sys-GMM, 2Sys-GMM, and Diff-GMM estimators to examine the effects of financial inclusion and other control predictors on economic growth. Based on statistical satisfaction, 2Sys-GMM has attained the preference and, thus, the conclusion is based on the findings from 2Sys-GMM estimators. The results clearly indicate that financial inclusion is a significant variable to influence economic growth in the full panel, income-level panels, and regional-level panels and causes the economies to foster rapid growth. The results obtained from the GMM estimates encouraged the study to delve into the causality relationship between financial inclusion, economic growth, and the control variables. In this regard, the results of the Dumitrescu and Hurlin [ 84 ] model extend the findings and provide evidence of bidirectional causality between financial inclusion and economic growth, while the results only support a unidirectional causality running from credit to the private sector, foreign direct investment, inflation rate, rule of law, school enrollment ratio, and trade openness with no feedback response. Moreover, the findings also failed to provide causality evidence for the age dependency ratio-economic growth and population growth-economic growth.

7.1 Policy recommendations

The findings extracted from a wide range of sophisticated methods and large panel spectra; suggest three important policy recommendations, among all others. First, it clearly indicates that financial inclusion is an assistive growth conduit in all economies regardless of any classification, and, thus, it is important to enhance the scope of its coverage via more extensive and swift channels, such as the advancement of financial services through financial technologies. This approach will lead to a higher and quicker integration of the excluded segment of society into formal financial systems and will maximize the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth. Second, it is imperative to gear policies to avert the existing digital gaps stemming from access inequality to digital technology. Informed investments in enhancing digital financial services including mobile banking and digital agent networking will substantially reduce the cost of transactions and encourage more entrants into the financial sector of an economy. Third, both public and private sector organizations need to provide an appropriate platform for hasty adaptation of financial technologies to pave the way for easy use of financial services by customers, enhance financial literacy to support effective use, and extend the scope of financial inclusion coverage. These policy measures will lead to extensive money circulation in the economy and growth channelization via higher financial system integration and investments.

7.2 Limitations of the study

Although the results are robust and cannot be doubted, the study suffers from one major limitation—that is, the use of the rule of law as a proxy for institutional quality, which may not be sufficient to capture the effects of institutional quality in its entirety. Future studies may overcome this shortcoming by including all institutional quality predictors, such as control of corruption, voice and accountability, government effectiveness, political stability, and regulatory quality when assessing the effects of financial inclusion on growth.

Supporting information

S1 appendix, s2 appendix, funding statement.

The author received no specific funding for this work.

Data Availability

  • PLoS One. 2022; 17(11): e0277730.

Decision Letter 0

25 Oct 2022

PONE-D-22-25867New insights into the impact of financial inclusion on economic growth: A global perspectivePLOS ONE

Dear Dr. Mohammad Naim Azimi,

Thank you for submitting your manuscript to PLOS ONE. After careful consideration, we feel that it has merit but does not fully meet PLOS ONE’s publication criteria as it currently stands. Therefore, we invite you to submit a revised version of the manuscript that addresses the points raised during the review process.

Please submit your revised manuscript by 26th November 2022. If you will need more time than this to complete your revisions, please reply to this message or contact the journal office at  gro.solp@enosolp . When you're ready to submit your revision, log on to https://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ and select the 'Submissions Needing Revision' folder to locate your manuscript file.

Please include the following items when submitting your revised manuscript:

  • A rebuttal letter that responds to each point raised by the academic editor and reviewer(s). You should upload this letter as a separate file labeled 'Response to Reviewers'.
  • A marked-up copy of your manuscript that highlights changes made to the original version. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Revised Manuscript with Track Changes'.
  • An unmarked version of your revised paper without tracked changes. You should upload this as a separate file labeled 'Manuscript'.

If you would like to make changes to your financial disclosure, please include your updated statement in your cover letter. Guidelines for resubmitting your figure files are available below the reviewer comments at the end of this letter.

If applicable, we recommend that you deposit your laboratory protocols in protocols.io to enhance the reproducibility of your results. Protocols.io assigns your protocol its own identifier (DOI) so that it can be cited independently in the future. For instructions see: https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/submission-guidelines#loc-laboratory-protocols . Additionally, PLOS ONE offers an option for publishing peer-reviewed Lab Protocol articles, which describe protocols hosted on protocols.io. Read more information on sharing protocols at https://plos.org/protocols?utm_medium=editorial-email&utm_source=authorletters&utm_campaign=protocols .

We look forward to receiving your revised manuscript.

Kind regards,

Ricky Chee Jiun Chia

Academic Editor

Journal Requirements:

When submitting your revision, we need you to address these additional requirements.

1. Please ensure that your manuscript meets PLOS ONE's style requirements, including those for file naming. The PLOS ONE style templates can be found at 

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=wjVg/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_main_body.pdf and 

https://journals.plos.org/plosone/s/file?id=ba62/PLOSOne_formatting_sample_title_authors_affiliations.pdf

[Note: HTML markup is below. Please do not edit.]

Reviewers' comments:

Reviewer's Responses to Questions

Comments to the Author

1. Is the manuscript technically sound, and do the data support the conclusions?

The manuscript must describe a technically sound piece of scientific research with data that supports the conclusions. Experiments must have been conducted rigorously, with appropriate controls, replication, and sample sizes. The conclusions must be drawn appropriately based on the data presented.

Reviewer #1: Yes

Reviewer #2: Yes

2. Has the statistical analysis been performed appropriately and rigorously?

3. Have the authors made all data underlying the findings in their manuscript fully available?

The PLOS Data policy requires authors to make all data underlying the findings described in their manuscript fully available without restriction, with rare exception (please refer to the Data Availability Statement in the manuscript PDF file). The data should be provided as part of the manuscript or its supporting information, or deposited to a public repository. For example, in addition to summary statistics, the data points behind means, medians and variance measures should be available. If there are restrictions on publicly sharing data—e.g. participant privacy or use of data from a third party—those must be specified.

4. Is the manuscript presented in an intelligible fashion and written in standard English?

PLOS ONE does not copyedit accepted manuscripts, so the language in submitted articles must be clear, correct, and unambiguous. Any typographical or grammatical errors should be corrected at revision, so please note any specific errors here.

5. Review Comments to the Author

Please use the space provided to explain your answers to the questions above. You may also include additional comments for the author, including concerns about dual publication, research ethics, or publication ethics. (Please upload your review as an attachment if it exceeds 20,000 characters)

Reviewer #1: The study presents the results of primary scientific research. It analyses effects of financial inclusion on economic growth from global angle with a large number of panels investigated by income and regional aspects from wide time range. The structure of the paper is satisfying. Theoretical background is well written indicating the importance of this research and emphasizing the potential gaps of the recent studies used by authors as basis of their research. Definition of the variables and their measurement are detail described and supported by other studies which additional rises the quality of the defined research model.

Econometric analyses are performed to a high technical standard and outputs described in detail to fully understand the relationships between key exogenous variable and target endogenous variable. The proposed research model is well defined taking into account also relevant control variables (choosed according to significance in prior studies) and so delivering comprehensive view on financial inclusion- economic growth linkage. All conclusion remarks are supported by the data. Some suggestion to author refers to lack of recognition of the research shortcoming and suggestions for future studies. Adding these would rise the quality of the research paper.

Reviewer #2: This paper investigates the impact of financial inclusion on economic growth from a global perspective, using the System-GMM method and classifying full panel, income level, and regional level for analysis, and finally also discusses the causal relationship between the two, which is more comprehensive. However, some of my comments are presented to share with the authors.

1.In my opinion, the author should write clearly the purpose and significance or importance of the research in the abstract section.

2.The introduction section feels repetitive with the literature section, mostly a list of literature. In the introduction section, the authors propose two key motives, "reflect consistent results on the effects of financial inclusion" (page 2) and " emerging paradigm shift" (page 2), which in my opinion means the same thing, and I do not understand the so-called two key motives of the authors.

3.Personally, I think there are many articles that do this direction, and I suggest that the authors provide a more novel viewpoint or perspective.

4.The literature review is preferably problem-oriented. What is the problem of the study? It is more laborious for the reader to read, and most literature covers too many issues and is not focused.

5.In the literature review section, the authors mention unemployment, stocks, poverty reduction, and the environment, etc., which I feel is far from the topic of this paper, so I suggest reducing the description of such cases. For example, "has negative effects on environmental quality through the flow of CO2 emissions" can be left out, which does not relate to the topic of the paper.

6.The Hausman test can determine whether a fixed effects model is chosen.

7.Whether Diff-GMM or Sys-GMM, the implementation of the GMM method actually requires preconditions. the GMM as an extension of instrumental variables does have natural advantages in controlling for endogeneity, but a set of assumptions should be satisfied, and it is suggested that the authors add robustness tests to ensure the validity of the estimation results. Examples include the Overidentification test or Hansen's J Test, testing Subsets of Orthogonality condition, classification based on different criteria, substituting with other similar variables, etc.

8.The premise of using System-GMM is that the data should be near the steady state, which means that the samples or individuals cannot be too far from the steady state during the observation period, otherwise the changes of these variables will be more related to the fixed effects, please confirm again whether the condition is satisfied.

9.Please report your options: vertical departure or difference; instrumental variables; lags of several periods; what kind of robust to choose (nonrobust, cluster-robust, or Windmeijer-corrected cluster-robust errors).

10.“considering the properties of the panel data used in this study, whether cointegrated or not, it employs the generalized method of moment (GMM), which is an appropriate econometric approach suitable for the case of this study”(page 7).In that case, is cointegration still needed in this paper? What is the significance of co-integration?

11.Please reconfirm whether the figures in the table are all three stars, i.e., significant at 1% condition. Please provide the test statistics in Table 6-Panel causality test results.

12.The author needs to adjust the format, or at least update the page and line numbers.

13.In the conclusion section, it is recommended to further discuss in depth what policies should be proposed in response to the findings of this paper. The policies proposed by the authors "First, governments need to turn substantial focus on the advancement of infrastructure ......"(page 15) are all ways in which financial inclusion should be achieved. The policy measures are unclear and unimpressive. Please suggest some specific and relevant policy measures from a global perspective based on the findings of the study.

14.Please identify and critically articulate the limitations of the study.

6. PLOS authors have the option to publish the peer review history of their article ( what does this mean? ). If published, this will include your full peer review and any attached files.

If you choose “no”, your identity will remain anonymous but your review may still be made public.

Do you want your identity to be public for this peer review? For information about this choice, including consent withdrawal, please see our Privacy Policy .

Reviewer #1: No

Reviewer #2: No

[NOTE: If reviewer comments were submitted as an attachment file, they will be attached to this email and accessible via the submission site. Please log into your account, locate the manuscript record, and check for the action link "View Attachments". If this link does not appear, there are no attachment files.]

While revising your submission, please upload your figure files to the Preflight Analysis and Conversion Engine (PACE) digital diagnostic tool,  https://pacev2.apexcovantage.com/ . PACE helps ensure that figures meet PLOS requirements. To use PACE, you must first register as a user. Registration is free. Then, login and navigate to the UPLOAD tab, where you will find detailed instructions on how to use the tool. If you encounter any issues or have any questions when using PACE, please email PLOS at  gro.solp@serugif . Please note that Supporting Information files do not need this step.

Author response to Decision Letter 0

28 Oct 2022

Response to reviewers

Manuscript: New insights into the impact of financial inclusion on economic growth: A global perspective

Date: October 28, 2022

Acknowledgement

First of all, I thank the respected editor and honorable reviewers for their constructive and valuable comments. Indeed, the incorporation of these comments has significantly improved the quality of the paper. All comments are fully incorporated into the manuscript. The respected reviewers may find the point-to-point revisions in the manuscript through the assigned colors. For reviewer #1, green; for reviewer # 2, yellow; for similar comments from reviewers #1 and # 2, grey; and for the editor’s comments, light blue, have been used. Furthermore, the revision can also be tracked via the track changes applied to the original manuscript.

Response to reviewer #1

Some suggestion to author refers to lack of recognition of the research shortcoming and suggestions for future studies. Adding these would rise the quality of the research paper.

Response: Sir, Thanks a lot for this valuable comment. The study imitations have been added in section 7 coded as “7.2 Limitations of the study.”

Response to reviewer #2

1. In my opinion, the author should write clearly the purpose and significance or importance of the research in the abstract section.

Response: Very true sir. The abstract has been motivated by the incorporation of the importance of the study.

2. The introduction section feels repetitive with the literature section, mostly a list of literature. In the introduction section, the authors propose two key motives, "reflect consistent results on the effects of financial inclusion" (page 2) and " emerging paradigm shift" (page 2), which in my opinion means the same thing, and I do not understand the so-called two key motives of the authors.

Response: Thank you sir for this valuable comment. To incorporate this comment, the following actions have been taken:

1) The repetition of sources in the introduction and literature review parts has been minimized to only two reference that provides the base of the notion and definition. The rest are revised and updated.

2) Based on your valuable comment, page 2, paragraph 4 has been totally revised to make it clearer. Now the key motivation is emphasized and the revised paragraph (4) clearly conveys the message.

3. Personally, I think there are many articles that do this direction, and I suggest that the authors provide a more novel viewpoint or perspective.

Response: Thank you sir for this constructive comment. From two aspects, we have gone through this direction. First, the journal’s “author guide” and instructs to follow this direction; and second, the acceptable standards. The novelty of the paper is clearly emphasized and we believe that this paper is rare in the existing literature.

4. The literature review is preferably problem-oriented. What is the problem of the study? It is more laborious for the reader to read, and most literature covers too many issues and is not focused.

Response: Thank you so much sire for this comment. The problem of study has been clearly indicated in the last paragraph of the section, page 5 “Literature review”. I think that is fair enough to reflect on the problems and missing gaps in the literature. If you are still not convinced, please let us know to highlight it more.

5. In the literature review section, the authors mention unemployment, stocks, poverty reduction, and the environment, etc., which I feel is far from the topic of this paper, so I suggest reducing the description of such cases. For example, "has negative effects on environmental quality through the flow of CO2 emissions" can be left out, which does not relate to the topic of the paper.

Response: Very true sir. The literature review has been revised and the irrelevant subjects have been removed.

6. The Hausman test can determine whether a fixed effects model is chosen.

Response: Thank you, sir. As an empirical approach to choose between Diff-GMM and Sys-GMM, the paper estimated the pooled OLS and fixed effects models. Therefore, the Hausman test has not applied to choose between fixed or random effect models.

7. Whether Diff-GMM or Sys-GMM, the implementation of the GMM method actually requires preconditions. the GMM as an extension of instrumental variables does have natural advantages in controlling for endogeneity, but a set of assumptions should be satisfied, and it is suggested that the authors add robustness tests to ensure the validity of the estimation results. Examples include the Overidentification test or Hansen's J Test, testing Subsets of Orthogonality condition, classification based on different criteria, substituting with other similar variables, etc.

Response: Thanks a lot, sir. Despite having all sets of econometric assumptions satisfied for the estimation of GMM, the diagnostic tests such as Hansen, Arellano-bond AR(1) and AR(2) are also reported in the rear part of Tables 4 and 5.

8. The premise of using System-GMM is that the data should be near the steady state, which means that the samples or individuals cannot be too far from the steady state during the observation period, otherwise the changes of these variables will be more related to the fixed effects, please confirm again whether the condition is satisfied.

Response: Exactly, sir. The near steady state of the panels classified under income-level and regional level has paved this way for the affirmation of the use of Sys-GMM over the Diff-GMM. However, the comparative results of the POLS and FE models also favor the use of the Sys-GMM model.

9. Please report your options: vertical departure or difference; instrumental variables; lags of several periods; what kind of robust to choose (nonrobust, cluster-robust, or Windmeijer-corrected cluster-robust errors).

Response: Thank you so much for this comment. It is now clearly reported in the manuscript (page 10, last paragraph) that for robustness, the study follows the Windmeijer (2005), which is an alternative to the differencing approach of Arellano and Bover (1995).

10. “considering the properties of the panel data used in this study, whether cointegrated or not, it employs the generalized method of moment (GMM), which is an appropriate econometric approach suitable for the case of this study” (page 7). In that case, is cointegration still needed in this paper? What is the significance of co-integration?

Response: Thank you, sir, for this constructive comment. In the case of our study, in an empirical sense, there is no need to estimate cointegration tests, while authors may still apply cointegration to examine any long-run relationship between the variables. Since the study hypothesized the existence of a long-run nexus amid predictors, it is beneficial to provide statistical evidence rather than making irrelevant judgments.

11. Please reconfirm whether the figures in the table are all three stars, i.e., significant at 1% condition. Please provide the test statistics in Table 6-Panel causality test results.

Response: Thanks a lot, sir. The significant levels are different and all are not significant at a 1% level. The W-statistics were already reported in the table but the p-values were omitted. Now, the p-values are reported under each W-stat. and thus, the relevant stars, *** presents 1%, ** presents 5%, and * presents 10% significance.

12. The author needs to adjust the format, or at least update the page and line numbers.

Response: Sir, thank you so much. The paper has been reformatted according to the journal’s requirements and the comment of the editor.

13. In the conclusion section, it is recommended to further discuss in depth what policies should be proposed in response to the findings of this paper. The policies proposed by the authors "First, governments need to turn substantial focus on the advancement of infrastructure ......"(page 15) are all ways in which financial inclusion should be achieved. The policy measures are unclear and unimpressive. Please suggest some specific and relevant policy measures from a global perspective based on the findings of the study.

Response: Very true sir. Two actions have been taken for this comment.

1) The recommendation part has been separated and are placed under “7.1 Policy recommendations” in section 7.

2) Policy measures are updated and connected to the findings to reflect clear measures from a global perspective.

14. Please identify and critically articulate the limitations of the study.

Response: Sir, I thank you so much for this constructive comment. The limitations of the study have been added in section 7 “7.1 Limitations of the study.”

Response to the editor

I thank a lot the respected editor for addressing the issues in the paper. For incorporating your comments, the following actions are taken:

1) The format of the paper is adjusted according to the journal’s requirement.

2) The referencing style has been changed to numbering style as required by the journal.

3) Title page has been added in the manuscript as required by the journal.

4) Main headings, sub-headings, and sub-sub-headings have been revised according to the journal’s instruction.

Submitted filename: Response to reviewers.docx

Decision Letter 1

PONE-D-22-25867R1

We’re pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been judged scientifically suitable for publication and will be formally accepted for publication once it meets all outstanding technical requirements.

Within one week, you’ll receive an e-mail detailing the required amendments. When these have been addressed, you’ll receive a formal acceptance letter and your manuscript will be scheduled for publication.

An invoice for payment will follow shortly after the formal acceptance. To ensure an efficient process, please log into Editorial Manager at http://www.editorialmanager.com/pone/ , click the 'Update My Information' link at the top of the page, and double check that your user information is up-to-date. If you have any billing related questions, please contact our Author Billing department directly at gro.solp@gnillibrohtua .

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please notify them about your upcoming paper to help maximize its impact. If they’ll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team as soon as possible -- no later than 48 hours after receiving the formal acceptance. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information, please contact gro.solp@sserpeno .

Additional Editor Comments (optional):

Acceptance letter

Dear Dr. Azimi:

I'm pleased to inform you that your manuscript has been deemed suitable for publication in PLOS ONE. Congratulations! Your manuscript is now with our production department.

If your institution or institutions have a press office, please let them know about your upcoming paper now to help maximize its impact. If they'll be preparing press materials, please inform our press team within the next 48 hours. Your manuscript will remain under strict press embargo until 2 pm Eastern Time on the date of publication. For more information please contact gro.solp@sserpeno .

If we can help with anything else, please email us at gro.solp@enosolp .

Thank you for submitting your work to PLOS ONE and supporting open access.

PLOS ONE Editorial Office Staff

on behalf of

Dr. Ricky Chee Jiun Chia

  • Economics & Finance
  • Foreign Policy
  • Domestic Policy
  • Health & Science
  • All Publications

Policies to Promote Economic Growth in the United States

Global market trends chart

Table of Contents

John w. diamond, george r. zodrow, share this publication.

  • Download PDF
  • Print This Publication

Diamond, John and George Zodrow. 2021. Policies to Promote Economic Growth in the United States . Policy brief: Recommendations for the New Administration. 01.23.21. Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy, Houston, Texas.

This brief is part of a series of policy recommendations for the administration of President Joe Biden. Focusing on a range of important issues facing the country, the briefs are intended to provide decision-makers with relevant and effective ideas for addressing domestic and foreign policy priorities. View the entire series at www.bakerinstitute.org/recommendations-2021 .

Introduction

The question of whether the United States is likely to continue on the robust growth path of earlier years or whether economic growth is likely to decelerate or even enter an extended period of “secular stagnation” is of critical importance to future living standards. In this policy brief, we examine: (1) the role of technology in promoting productivity growth, (2) the relationship between labor markets and economic growth, including the importance of human capital accumulation and the role of immigration; and (3) the effects of fiscal policy, including both expenditure and tax reform, on the prospects for growth. 1

Advances in Technology and Economic Growth

The effects of advances in technology on economic growth are highly controversial, with a huge chasm between the views of the “techno-optimists” and the “technopessimists.” The techno-pessimists argue that recent technological advances, such as artificial intelligence (AI) and information communication technologies, are not as transformative as earlier revolutionary general purpose technologies—such as the steam engine, electricity, and the internal combustion engine—so that the slowdown in productivity growth experienced over the past 50 years is likely to continue. By comparison, the “techno-optimists” argue that recent and future productivity and growth-enhancing developments in AI, robotics, and digitally connected sensors will, after a lag of undetermined length, spark a new era of technology-induced increases in productivity that will lead to significantly faster economic growth. Indeed, this view has led to concerns that such increases in productivity will eventually be so dramatic and will occur so rapidly that they will significantly increase unemployment over time, leading to often-discussed concerns about the “future of work” and prospects for significant and persistent unemployment.

The evidence thus far can be broadly interpreted in two ways. On the one hand, the largely tepid growth in productivity despite significant technological advances over most of the last 50 years is consistent with the techno-pessimist story. On the other hand, the argument that significant amounts of time may be required before technological advances are translated into productivity gains, but such gains could eventually be significant (Hubbard, forthcoming) strikes us as quite plausible. Moreover, the fact that recent significant technological advances have not been rapidly translated into large productivity gains suggests that problems with increasing unemployment will develop slowly. This in turn increases the likelihood that, over time, technological advances will, as they have with technological advances in the past, lead not only to productivity growth and increases in aggregate wealth and living standards but also to increases in employment attributable to the creation of many complementary and new jobs, many of which will be robot-assisted and some of which may not yet even be envisioned—results that will mitigate employment concerns, especially if the transition is lengthy and gradual. Moreover, declines in the size of the labor force due to aging of the population (and perhaps to reduced immigration) should also help limit the problems associated with technology-induced job losses.

Our view is that this debate about the implications of technological advances for economic growth suggests two broad directions for public policy. First, the United States should promote future productivity growth by facilitating increased innovation, including in AI, robotics, and digital sensors. Expanded government support for research and development (R&D), especially basic research, is appropriate. In particular, recent declines in real federal R&D spending are extremely troubling, as are recent proposals to further cut such spending. In addition, the provision in the recently enacted Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA) that will require five-year amortization of R&D expenses— rather than the long-standing treatment of immediate expensing—seems singularly misguided. (The maintenance of the incremental R&D credit is also appropriate, given the positive externalities associated with such investment.)

Second, we can limit technology-induced job losses by significantly augmenting existing policies for retraining, ongoing education, increasing mobility, and income support during the transition between jobs—consistent with the often-expressed theoretical arguments that changes that improve aggregate welfare but cause individual losses should be accompanied by compensation for those losses. The United States currently provides such assistance for trade-related job losses under the Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) program, but the TAA program is minuscule in comparison to the losses suffered. It should be expanded and better designed, applying more generally to job displacement including that associated with technological advances, and provide funds for lifelong learning and training programs and workforce development.

Labor and Economic Growth

Increasing labor productivity is clearly of critical importance to maintaining economic growth. Cunha (forthcoming) argues that the key to improving the skills of the labor force, especially at the lower end of the income distribution, is to promote college readiness among children who grow up in low-income households and to improve the matches between college-ready, low-income students and colleges; he stresses that college readiness requires investments in children at a very early age, coupled with parental education. This implies that resources in the United States should be focused on both education designed to enhance cognitive skills and the development of socio-emotional skills at early (preschool) ages for low-income children—rather than the enactment of expensive non-means-tested proposals for tuition-free college at two-year colleges and all public universities. Providing college-ready low-income students with better guidance regarding opportunities at more selective institutions, especially information about the application process and available financial aid, would also generate large returns.

Another way to expand the labor force is through immigration. For example, Borjas (forthcoming) argues that admitting high-skill immigrants is the policy most likely to increase economic growth, especially if such immigrants have positive external effects on the productivity of native workers. We would add two caveats or extensions. First, the children of immigrants have relatively higher rates of upward income mobility, which suggests that a policy focusing on admitting high-skill immigrants may exclude some individuals who would ultimately be highly productive members of society. Second, some anecdotal immigrant success stories suggest that the externalities generated by immigrants may be quite large in some cases. For example, more than 40% of Fortune 500 companies in 2017 were founded or cofounded by an immigrant or the child of an immigrant, with an immigrant share of 57% for the top thirty-five companies in that group. This suggests strongly that cutbacks in immigration at a time of concern about future economic growth prospects are counterproductive.

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Finally, tax and expenditure policy can have significant effects on economic growth. For example, as stressed by Feldstein (forthcoming), an important issue limiting growth prospects in the United States is the unsustainable nature of current fiscal policy—although the present environment of extremely low interest rates and inflation has reduced the urgency of addressing this issue in comparison to previous years. Feldstein makes a persuasive case for raising revenues by reducing tax expenditures and enacting a carbon tax, as well as reducing entitlement spending to control deficits and increases in the national debt. In Diamond and Zodrow (forthcoming), we argue that implementing a carbon tax, even neglecting its considerable benefits in terms of reducing carbon emissions and other pollutants, would either have small negative effects on economic growth or actually increase growth, and would not necessarily have a regressive impact on the distribution of income, depending on how the revenues from the tax are used.

Additional tax reforms, especially for the taxation of business income, would also be conducive to growth. For example, we would complete the movement to a cashflow tax with expensing at the business level that was partially enacted under the TCJA, including eliminating all deductions for interest expenses. With full expensing, the corporate income tax rate could be raised somewhat—to around 25%— although concerns about both the mobility of firm-specific capital that generates economic rents and income shifting should preclude further increases. The provisions limiting tax avoidance under the TCJA should also be enhanced.

In summary, continued robust economic growth in the United States will, among many other things, require policies that encourage rapid technological innovation and increases in productivity, encourage increases in the stock of human capital, promote investment while reducing debt, and maximize economic efficiency, including minimizing the distortions caused by the tax system. The discussions in Diamond and Zodrow (forthcoming) provide an insightful and provocative roadmap for achieving these critical objectives.

1. For wide-ranging discussions of these issues, see John W. Diamond and George R. Zodrow, Prospects for Economic Growth in the United States , Cambridge University Press, forthcoming, 2021. The volume will include all papers cited in this policy brief: Glenn Hubbard, “The $64,000 Question: Living in the Age of Technogical Possibility or Showing Possibility's Age?”; Flávio Cunha, “Human Capital and Long-Run Economic Growth”; George Borjas, “Immigration and Economic Growth”; and Martin Feldstein, “The Future of Economic Growth in the United States.”

This material may be quoted or reproduced without prior permission, provided appropriate credit is given to the author and Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy. The views expressed herein are those of the individual author(s), and do not necessarily represent the views of Rice University’s Baker Institute for Public Policy.

Related Research

Stock market chart

Debate Over the New Digital Asset Broker Reporting Rules: Striking the Right Balance

Kindergarten children in classroom

Baker Briefing: America’s Child Care Problem

Capitol flag

The House’s Tax Relief Plan Is a Lesson in Poorly Designed Fiscal Policy

Cart

  • SUGGESTED TOPICS
  • The Magazine
  • Newsletters
  • Managing Yourself
  • Managing Teams
  • Work-life Balance
  • The Big Idea
  • Data & Visuals
  • Reading Lists
  • Case Selections
  • HBR Learning
  • Topic Feeds
  • Account Settings
  • Email Preferences

Research: How Entrepreneurship Can Revitalize Local Communities

how can research help in fostering economic growth

An eight-year study of two Detroit-based accelerators reveals the pitfalls of “scaling up” — and the promise of “scaling deep.”

Much has been written about the potential for entrepreneurship to spur economic growth — and yet time and time again, we’ve seen business-driven revitalization programs fail to make a real, lasting impact on their local communities. What will it take to foster ventures that actually revive the economies in which they’re founded? The authors discuss the results of an eight-year investigation into two organizations that took opposing approaches to supporting entrepreneurs in Detroit. They argue that if the goal is to harness the power of entrepreneurship to revitalize impoverished places, business leaders and policymakers must shift away from a focus on scaling up, and that they must instead encourage founders to “scale deep” — that is, to grow slowly and become strongly embedded into the local economy, rather than growing as quickly and broadly as possible. This means investing not only in ventures that offer strong financial returns, but also in those that lift up their communities to achieve sustained self-reliance.

Both business leaders and policymakers have long understood the potential of entrepreneurship to foster local development. From Kenya’s Silicon Savannah to business-driven revitalization efforts in Detroit , Baltimore , and other urban areas, programs abound to revive local economies through entrepreneurial training, investment, and accelerators.

  • Suntae Kim is Assistant Professor of Management and Organization at Johns Hopkins Carey Business School. He studies how innovation emerges out of adversity, in the context of urban entrepreneurship, minority entrepreneurship, and crisis management. He received his doctoral degree in Business Administration from University of Michigan.
  • AK Anna Kim is Assistant Professor in Management for Sustainability at Desautels Faculty of Management, McGill University. She received her PhD from the University of Cambridge. Anna’s research explores sustainable development through the lens of time and space, with a particular focus on the coordination of short- and long-term considerations in impoverished communities.

Partner Center

ResearchFDI

The Crucial Role of Workforce Development Programs in Fostering Economic Growth

In today’s rapidly evolving global economy, the success and competitiveness of local economies are heavily reliant on a skilled and adaptable workforce. Thus, workforce development programs play a pivotal role in shaping the economic landscape of any country or region. These programs are designed to enhance the skills, knowledge, and capabilities of the workforce, ensuring they remain competitive, adaptable, and relevant in an ever-evolving job market.   

This two-part article explores the crucial role of workforce development programs in nurturing economic growth and development.  

In the first part of this two-part article, we will explore the importance of workforce development programs, the key elements of an effective program, and their positive impact on economic growth and development. Stay tuned for part two next week, where we will provide our guide on enhancing economic growth through workplace development trainings designed for economic development professionals.  

What is Workforce Development?  

Workforce development can be defined as a comprehensive set of strategies, programs, and initiatives aimed at enhancing the skills, knowledge, and capabilities of the workforce in a particular region or industry. These trainings are aimed at enhancing the capabilities of the workforce, ensuring they stay relevant and adaptable in their respective industries. Workforce development programs can encompass a wide range of areas, including technical skills, soft skills, leadership development, and industry-specific knowledge.  

Workforce development training not only allows individuals to stay up-to-date and competitive in their fields but also encourages innovation and productivity within companies. By investing in the development of the workforce, businesses can build a more skilled workforce, which improves job satisfaction, reduces turnover, and ultimately, provides higher organizational success. Furthermore, workforce development training also has a positive impact on communities as it creates a more competent and adaptable workforce, contributing to economic growth and overall societal advancement.  

As a result, by investing in workforce development , governments, businesses and organizations foster a more competitive and resilient labor force, leading to increased productivity and reduced unemployment.  

Understanding the Importance of Workforce Development for Economic Growth

Workforce development plays a crucial role in fostering economic growth and development. As industries and technologies continue to evolve, it is essential that the workforce also evolves in order to meet market demands. Investing in workforce development ensures that businesses have a skilled workforce capable of driving innovation, increasing productivity, and staying competitive in the global market.  

However, workforce development offers benefits beyond just companies. Workforce development contributes to the overall economic growth and development of a region. Through bridging the skills gap, enhancing the competitiveness of a region and finally through fostering economic resilience, workforce development programs create educated and skilled workforces, attracting foreign investments, thus leading to economic expansion and job creation.  

Bridging the Skills Gap

The skills gap is one of the largest challenges that today’s workforce faces. As industries and technologies continue to evolve, there is a growing mismatch between the skills and qualifications possessed by the available workforce and the skills required by employers to fill specific job roles effectively. It is a significant challenge faced by businesses and industries, with McKinsey reporting that, 40% of American employers are struggling to find people with the skills they need, even for entry-level jobs. Workforce development programs have emerged as crucial tools in bridging the skills gap. These programs address the growing need for a highly skilled and adaptable labor force by providing individuals with relevant training and education that aligns with the demands of the job market. By focusing on both hard and soft skills, these initiatives empower participants to acquire competencies that match the evolving needs of various industries. Thus, these programs not only help individuals secure gainful employment but also contribute significantly to economic growth and overall social well-being of a region by fostering a competent and capable workforce.   

Enhancing Competitiveness

Workforce development programs not only bridge the skills gap but also enhance a region’s competitiveness. These programs promote the development of a skilled and versatile workforce, which in turn attracts investments from companies looking for qualified professionals. This leads to the creation and expansion of businesses in the area. Furthermore, skilled workers drive innovation, adopt cutting-edge technologies, and contribute to the development of new products and services, thereby positioning their regions as leaders in their respective industries. Ultimately, a region with a strong focus on workforce development can position itself as an attractive destination for businesses, talent, and economic growth, bolstering its overall competitiveness in the national and international marketplaces.  

Fostering Economic Resilience

In addition to enhancing competitiveness, workforce development programs also foster economic resilience. In a fast-paced job market, individuals need to stay relevant and adaptable to remain employable. By continuously learning and upskilling, individuals can weather economic fluctuations and remain valuable assets to businesses. Investing in workforce development enables communities to build a well-trained and versatile workforce that can quickly pivot to meet the demands of emerging industries or adapt to changes in the labor market, reducing the impact of economic downturns. Furthermore, workforce programs encourage lifelong learning, empowering workers to embrace continuous education as an integral part of their professional growth, enabling continuous upskilling and reskilling. By fostering a robust and adaptable workforce, workforce development programs strengthen the foundation of the economy, making it more resilient to external shocks and challenges. This resilience not only sustains economic growth in times of uncertainty but also fosters an environment conducive to attracting new investments and creating opportunities for further development and prosperity.  

Developing Effective Workforce Development Programs

To reap the benefits that workforce development can offer, it is crucial to ensure that these programs are effective and target the areas most needed. However, developing effective workforce development programs is often a struggle due to a number of interconnected and complex factors. Due to the diverse and dynamic nature of many industries, these programs often struggle to be responsive enough to address evolving industry needs. Furthermore, fostering the needed partnerships between educational institutions, employers, and government entities can be complex, as their differing priorities and approaches need to be harmonized for the program’s success. Finally, addressing the diverse needs of the program’s participants, which includes the varying skill levels and backgrounds, also requires an adaptable and inclusive approach. Overcoming these challenges and developing an effective workforce development program can be difficult.  

Based on extensive research on global workforce-development programs and economic strategies, McKinsey has identified five principles that should be the foundation of developing workforce-development programs.  

1. Define Geographic Assets and Target Professions

To build effective workforce-development programs, it is essential to start by defining geographic assets and identifying target professions. Local and state agencies must gain a comprehensive understanding of their starting point, considering the complexities of local economies. Job-market analyses should be conducted to identify sectors with high growth potential and workforce shortages. Collaboration between industry leaders, education providers, government agencies, and trade associations in identifying the highest priorities on which to focus has also proven to yield the best results.  

2. Deliver ROI to Employers and Workers

To gain buy-in from employers and participants it is crucial that the return on investment (ROI) for workforce-development programs is evident. The current lack of evidence linking these programs to business performance has made employers more hesitant to participate or fund them. Thus, metrics should be developed to track the cost of program recruitment and training, employer productivity and retention rates, and speed to promotion.  

3. Support Comprehensive, Demand-Driven Training

The success of workforce-development programs depends on comprehensive and demand-driven training approaches. Successful programs involve employers from the start, utilizing on-the-job observations of high-scarcity or high-turnover professions to reveal the critical skills needed for success. Furthermore, collaboration between employers, employees and training providers that places a focus on accessibility regarding the delivery approach of the trainings has proven to yield higher completion rates, ensuring the efficiency and effectiveness of these programs.  

  4. Assess and Prepare Learners

Effective workforce-development programs start by ensuring that learners meet the necessary requirements for their chosen professions and preparing them for the training. This can be done through basic screenings aimed at assessing skill levels and transparency regarding the job they are training for, including its positive and negative aspects. Assessing and preparing learners has proven to improve retention in both the program and the subsequent employment and ensures that program resources are allocated to those most likely to benefit.  

5. Coordinate the Workforce-Development Process Centrally

Finally, a central coordination approach is needed to optimize the impact of workforce-development programs. Currently, despite the growing popularity of workforce development programs and the substantial investments in these programs, many continue to operate in isolation without integration with other essential services, hindering the learner’s success in completing training, finding employment, and succeeding in their career. Thus, to ensure the effectiveness of these programs, the workforce development process requires coordinated efforts among different entities, with clear outcome goals and provision of necessary support for learners.  

In Conclusion…

Workforce development programs play a pivotal role in fostering economic growth and development in our ever-changing world. These initiatives not only equip individuals with the necessary skills and knowledge to meet the demands of the job market but also contribute to building a resilient and competitive workforce. By investing in continuous learning and upskilling, regions and businesses can empower their workforce to adapt to technological advancements and industry shifts, positioning them at the forefront of innovation and productivity.  

  • The Rule Of Law And IP Rights Protection: Key Factors In Attracting FDI To The US
  • The Importance of the US Workforce in Attracting FDI
  • Building Stronger Communities: Understanding The Power Of Community Economic Development
  • Research Uncensored Podcast – Ft.  Len Magyar and Sean Dyke

stef small

Stefan Calimanu

Related posts.

Destination Branding: Strategic Insights for Economic Development Experts

  • Destination Branding: Strategic Insights for Economic Development Experts

Unpacking the Place Branding Process 

  • Unpacking the Place Branding Process 

Place vs. Destination Branding: Their Vital Role in Economic Development

  • Place vs. Destination Branding: Their Vital Role in Economic Development

Recent Posts

  • ResearchFDI Relocates to New Headquarters in Downtown Montreal
  • ResearchFDI and Tractus Form Strategic Partnership to Enhance Global Investment and Trade Services
  • Announcements
  • FDI Insights
  • News & Media
  • Press Release
  • Uncategorized

ResearchFDI Investment Attraction

FDI365 is a customized online business intelligence platform designed for investment attraction and economic development professionals .

Our Services

  • Lead Generation & Qualification
  • B2B Trade Development
  • FDI Training
  • Business Intelligence Solutions
  • Representation
  • Business Retention & Expansion
  • Economic Development Strategy
  • Client Testimonials
  • Case Studies

Subscribe to our newsletter

Search the website:, let's discuss your next project.

Amber - investment leads

One of our consultants will review your strategy and provide actionable tips to help you reach your investment attraction goals. 100% free & no-obligation!

How the Government Can Help Stimulate Economic Growth

  • First Online: 23 October 2021

Cite this chapter

Book cover

  • Jeffrey Yi-Lin Forrest 3 &
  • Yong Liu 4  

Part of the book series: Contributions to Management Science ((MANAGEMENT SC.))

970 Accesses

This chapter, which is mainly based on Forrest et al. (to appear, The role government policy and supports play to stimulate economic growth), studies the following three issues: (1) why policy tools of the government might work in real life; (2) when they do work, what the underlying mechanism is through which implemented policies play their roles; and (3) why it is necessary for the government to design and implement policies and provide supports for the purpose of stimulating economic growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
  • Durable hardcover edition

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Adner, R. (2006). Match your innovation strategy to your innovation ecosystem. Harvard Business Review, 84 (4), 98–107.

Google Scholar  

Andreoni, A., & Chang, H. J. (2019). The political economy of industrial policy. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 48 (March), 136–150.

Article   Google Scholar  

Auclert, A. (2019). Monetary policy and the redistribution channel. American Economic Review, 109 (6), 2333–2367.

Boeckx, J., de Sola Perea, M., & Peersman, G. (2016). The transmission mechanism of credit support policies in the Euro Area . National Bank of Belgium Working Paper, No. 302.

Chemers, M. M. (2001). Cognitive, social, and emotional intelligence of transformational leadership: Efficacy and effectiveness. In R. E. Riggio, S. E. Murphy, & F. J. Pirozzolo (Eds.), Multiple intelligences and leadership (pp. 139–160). Lawrence Erlbaum.

Christensen, C. M., Suárez, F. F., & Utterback, J. M. (1998). Strategies for survival in fast-changing industries. Management Science, 44 (12-part-2), S207–S220.

Coleman, D. C. (1983). Proto-industrialization: A concept too many. The Economic History Review (New Series), 36 (3), 435–448.

Cúrdia, V., & Woodford, M. (2016). Credit frictions and optimal monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 84 (December), 30–65.

Fleischman, R. K., & Parker, L. D. (2017). What is past is prologue: Costing accounting in the British industrial revolution, 1760-1850 . Routledge.

Book   Google Scholar  

Forrest, J. Y. L. (2018). General systems theory: Foundation, intuition and applications in business decision making . Springer.

Forrest, J. Y. L., Duan, X. J., Zhao, C. L., & Xu, L. D. (2013). Systems science: Methodological approaches . CRC Press, an imprint of Taylor and Francis.

Forrest, J. Y.-L., Jallow, A. K., Wen, C., Shi, J. H., & Guo, H. (n.d.). (to appear). The role government policy and supports play to stimulate economic growth. Submitted for publication.

Forrest, J. Y. L., Zhao, H. C., & Shao, L. (2018). Engineering rapid industrial revolutions for impoverished agrarian nations. Theoretical Economics Letters, 8 , 2594–2630.

Fultz, D., Long, R. R., Owens, G. V., Bohan, W., Kaylor, R., and Weil, J. (1959). Studies of thermal convection in a rotating cylinder with some implications for large-scale atmospheric motion. Meteorol. Monographs (American Meteorological Society), 21 (4).

Government of Japan. (2015). https://www8.cao.go.jp/cstp/kihonkeikaku/5basicplan_en.pdf , Accessed on April 16, 2019.

Hall, W., & Pesenti, J. (2017). Growing the artificial intelligence industry in the UK. https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/652097/Growing_the_artificial_intelligence_industry_in_the_UK.pdf , Accessed on October 15, 2017.

Hemphill, T. A. (2014). The US advanced manufacturing initiative: Will it be implemented as an innovation – Or industrial – Policy? Innovation: Organization & Management, 16 (1), 67–70.

Hermann, M., Pentek, T., & Otto, B. (2016). Design principles for industry 4.0 scenarios. The 49th Hawaii international conference on system sciences (HICSS) , Koloa, HI (pp. 3928–3937).

Howell, T. R., Noellert, W. A., MacLaughlin, J. H., & Wolff, A. W. (2019). The microelectronics race: The impact of government policy on international competition . Routledge.

Huntington, S. P. (1996). The clash of civilizations and the remaking of world order . Simon & Schuster.

Iansiti, M., & Levien, R. (2004). The keystone advantage . Harvard Business School Press.

Jaehrling, K., Johnson, M., Larsen, T. P., Refslund, B., & Grimshaw, D. (2018). Tackling precarious work in public supply chains. Work, Employment and Society, 32 (3), 546–563.

Jomo, K. S. (2019). Southeast Asia’s misunderstood miracle: Industrial policy and economic development in Thailand, Malaysia and Indonesia . Routledge.

Klir, G. (2001). Facets of systems science . Springer.

Kouzes, J., & Posner, B. (2007). The leadership challenge . Jossey Bass.

Li, T., & Ma, J. H. (2015). Complexity analysis of dual-channel game model with different managers’ business objectives. Communications in Nonlinear Science and Numerical Simulation, 20 , 199–208.

Lin, Y. (1988). An application of systems analysis in sociology. Cybernetics and Systems: An International Journal, 19 , 267–278.

Lin, Y. (1999). General systems theory: A mathematical approach . Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers.

Lin, Y. (2009). Systemic yoyos: Some impacts of the second dimension . Auerbach Publication, an imprint of Taylor and Francis.

Lin, Y., & Forrest, B. (2011). Systemic structure behind human organizations: From civilizations to individuals . Springer.

Marc, S., Yann, B., Charly, B, et al. (2018). Mission Villani: for a meaningful artificial intelligence towards a French and European strategy. https://www.aiforhumanity.fr/pdfs/MissionVillani_Report_ENG-VF.pdf , Accessed on March 8, 2018.

Mendels, F. F. (1972). Proto-industrialization: The first phase of the industrialization process. The Journal of Economic History, 32 , 241–261. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0022050700075495

OWH. (2016). Preparing for the Future of Artificial Intelligence. https://obamawhitehouse.archives.gov/sites/default/files/whitehouse_files/microsites/ostp/NSTC/preparing_for_the_future_of_ai.pdf , Accessed on April 20, 2019.

Petrovslaya, I., Zaverskiy, S., & Kiseleva, E. (2017). Attribute to entrepreneurship in Russia. Advances in Systems Science and Applications, 17 (2), 29–43.

Porter, M. E. (1985). Competitive advantage: Creating and sustaining superior performance . Free Press.

Rebei, N. (2017). Evaluating changes in the transmission mechanism of government spending shocks. International Monetary Fund, WP/17/49.

Rostow, W. W. (1960). The stages of economic growth: A non-communist manifesto . Cambridge University Press.

Sobel, R. (1999). When giants stumble: Classic business blunders and how to avoid them . Prentice Hall.

State Council of the PRC. (2015). Notice of State Council of the PRC on printing and distributing “Made in China 2025”. http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/content/2015-05/19/content_9784.htm , Accessed on May 8, 2015.

Wen, Y. (2016). The making of an economic superpower: Unlocking China’s secret of rapid industrialization . World Scientific.

Wieczorek, A. J., & Hekkert, M. P. (2012). Systemic instruments for systemic innovation problems. Science and Public Policy, 39 (1), 74–87.

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Department of Accounting, Economics and Finance, Slippery Rock University of Pennsylvania, Slippery Rock, PA, USA

Jeffrey Yi-Lin Forrest

School of Business, Jiangnan University, Wuxi, Jiangsu, China

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Forrest, J.YL., Liu, Y. (2022). How the Government Can Help Stimulate Economic Growth. In: Value in Business. Contributions to Management Science. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-82898-1_19

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-82898-1_19

Published : 23 October 2021

Publisher Name : Springer, Cham

Print ISBN : 978-3-030-82897-4

Online ISBN : 978-3-030-82898-1

eBook Packages : Business and Management Business and Management (R0)

Share this chapter

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research

house icon

December 2022 - You are accessing an archived version of our website. This website is no longer maintained or updated. The Sustainable Development Knowledge Platform has been migrated here: https://sdgs.un.org/

You will be redirected to the new Partnership Platform in 10 seconds.

how can research help in fostering economic growth

  • What factors can influence the transition to a global economy that creates wellbeing, sustainability and reduction of inequality?
  • What types of strategies and policies have proven effective for the promotion of inclusive and sustainable economic growth?
  • What mechanisms would ensure a faster transition to sustainable consumption and production patterns?
  • H.E. Mr. Sven Jürgenson, Permanent Representative of Estonia to the UN and Vice President of ECOSOC
  • Mr. Vinicius Pinheiro, Director of the NY Office of the International Labour Organization (ILO)
  • Mr. Tim Jackson, Director of the Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity (CUSP) and Professor of Sustainable Development at the University of Surrey
  • Mr. Bart Verspagen, Director-Dean of the Maastricht Graduate School of Governance (MGSoG) at Maastricht University and Director of United Nations University – Maastricht Economic and Social Research Institute on Innovation and Technology (UNU-MERIT)
  • Mr. Dyborn Chibonga, Chief Executive Officer at the National Smallholder Farmers' Association of Malawi (NASFAM)
  • Mr. Wellington Chibebe, Deputy General Secretary of the International Trade Union Confederation (ITUC)

Director-Dean of the Maastricht Graduate School of Governance (MGSoG) and Director of UNU (UNU-MERIT)

Mr. Verspagen is an economist specialised in the economics of innovation, growth and development. Since 2012, he is the Director of the UNU-MERIT, a research and training institute of United Nations University, which collaborates closely with Maastricht University and carries out research and training on a range of social, political and economic factors that drive economic development in a global perspective. The institute is also a UN think tank that has the mission, among others, to research how countries can catch up in the unequal global playing field of the 21st century, without increasing inequality and social exclusion. Verspagen’s research interests are centred around the process of economic growth and development, especially its relation to innovation and technological change. His research field also covers areas such as international trade, development economics, industrial dynamics, economic history, and applied econometrics, statistics and mathematical modelling, including simulation modelling of international economies.

Chief Executive Officer at the National Smallholder Farmers' Association of Malawi (NASFAM)

Mr. Chibonga manages the National Smallholder Farmers’ Association of Malawi (NASFAM) as Chief Executive Officer. He has served in this role since June 1999, managing the membership association of over 100,000 farmer members and a staff of about 390 in 19 locations across the country. NASFAM pioneered the establishment of The Agricultural Commodity Exchange for Africa (ACE) in 2004, entered into Fairtrade production of peanuts in 2005 and won the Yara Prize for an African Green Revolution in 2009. Mr. Chibonga holds a Masters Certificate in NGO Management and M.Sc. in Landscape Ecology Design and Maintenance from Wye College (University of London). He also has a B.Sc. (Credit) and Diploma (Credit) from Bunda College of Agriculture (University of Malawi).

Director of the Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity (CUSP) and Professor of Sustainable Development at the University of Surrey

Mr. Jackson is Professor of Sustainable Development at the University of Surrey and Director of the Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity (CUSP) funded by the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC). He currently holds a Professorial Fellowship on Prosperity and Sustainability in the Green Economy (PASSAGE) also funded by the ESRC. He has been at the forefront of international debates about sustainable development for over two decades and has worked closely with the UK Government, the United Nations, and numerous private companies and NGOs to bring social science research into sustainability. Between 2004 and 2011, he was Economics Commissioner on the UK Sustainable Development Commission, where his work culminated in the publication of his controversial best-seller “Prosperity without Growth: economics for a finite planet.” His research interests focus on the economic and social aspects of the relationship between people’s lifestyles and the environment. In addition to this Tim is an award-winning playwright with numerous radio-writing credits for the BBC.

ILO Special Representative to the United Nations and Director of the ILO Office for the United Nations

Mr. Pinheiro is the ILO Special Representative to the United Nations and Director of the ILO Office for the UN since February 2016. He is also the Executive Secretary of the Social Protection Interagency Board and the ILO representative in the United Nations Development Group. From 2012 to 2015 he was the lead advisor on employment and social protection issues to the UN negotiations on the Agenda 2030 supporting member states in the definition of goals and targets in the area of decent work. Before moving to New York, Mr. Pinheiro served as the Executive Secretary of the Social Protection Floor Advisory Group, led by Ms. Michelle Bachelet, whose work led ultimately to the adoption of the ILO Recommendation 202 on National Floors of Social Protection. From 1999 to 2002 Mr. Pinheiro was Vice-minister of Social Security of Brazil and State Secretary for Social Security responsible for a major pension reform and for measures to extend the social protection coverage.

Deputy General Secretary, International Trade Union Confederation (ITUC)

Wellington Chibebe was elected Deputy General Secretary of the ITUC in 2011. Prior to taking up that position, he served as Secretary General of the Zimbabwe Congress of Trade Unions (ZCTU). He joined the ZCTU in 2001 having previously served as President of the National Railway Workers’ Union, which he joined in 1988 after serving his apprenticeship as a diesel plant fitter. He holds a Bachelor of Laws Degree (LLB) from the University of South Africa (UNISA). Wellington Chibebe has represented Zimbabwe’s trade union movement on numerous occasions at the annual ILO International Labour Conference and various other major international meetings. A champion for democracy and development, he was awarded the inaugural Arther Svensson International Award for Trade Union Rights by the Norwegian Chemical Workers’ Federation in 2010. In 2014, Wellington Chibebe was re-elected as ITUC Deputy General Secretary.

IMAGES

  1. Finding a Way to Boost Economic Growth

    how can research help in fostering economic growth

  2. Why should I care about economic growth?

    how can research help in fostering economic growth

  3. Benefits of economic growth

    how can research help in fostering economic growth

  4. Factors and measures that foster economic growth through the IoT

    how can research help in fostering economic growth

  5. Economic Recovery and Fostering Growth

    how can research help in fostering economic growth

  6. The Role of Stock Exchanges in Fostering Economic Growth and

    how can research help in fostering economic growth

VIDEO

  1. Empowering Tech Talent for Economic Growth: Inside Our Academy

  2. Top 10 UK Economic Policies That Drive Growth and Stability

  3. Strengthening vaccine delivery and uptake in Africa. How can research help?

  4. National Development Co.: Fostering Inclusive Growth

  5. The Power of Circulating Money: Benefits for Many

  6. "Prime Minister's Endorsement: Revolutionizing India Through Direct Selling Network Marketing"

COMMENTS

  1. Why Research on Economic Growth Is Important? Future Research Areas on

    Flexibility, agility and stability in economic growth: Economic growth is a complex system consisting of diverse components and activities, which are interacting and changing in different ways over time. Scholars have a chance to explore evolutionary processes and complex transformation in economic growth, with particular emphasis on the nature ...

  2. IMF: Research and development is crucial for economic growth

    Emerging Technologies. Follow. Analysis by the IMF suggests that research and development are vital for economic progress. Cross-border collaboration is also crucial to help foster the innovation needed for long-term growth. COVID-19 vaccines are an example of innovation, helping save lives and bring forward the reopening of many economies.

  3. Why Basic Science Matters for Economic Growth

    Small increases over time improve living standards. We estimate that a 10 percent permanent increase in the stock of a country's own basic research can increase productivity by 0.3 percent. The impact of the same increase in the stock of foreign basic research is larger. Productivity increases by 0.6 percent.

  4. The impact of research output on economic growth by fields ...

    The empirical results on the relationship between academic knowledge/research output and economic growth is far from clear-cut or conclusive. The empirical literature can be divided into two main set of studies (see Table 1).The first includes studies that consider global research output, without distinguishing research fields (De Moya-Anegón and Herrero-Solana 1999; Lee et al. 2011; Inglesi ...

  5. Why Research on Economic Growth Is Important? Future Research Areas on

    Why Research on Economic Growth Is Important? Future Research Areas on Economic Growth. ... Stock markets, corporate finance, and economic growth: An overview. The World Bank Economic Review, 10(2), 223-239. Crossref. Google Scholar. Doré N. I., & Teixeira A. A. (2021). Empirical literature on economic growth, 1991-2020: Uncovering extant ...

  6. Academic Research

    The Growth Lab's research aims to uncover the mechanisms behind economic growth. We approach this challenge from the perspective that economic development involves not just producing more of the same, but also upgrading the composition of what a place produces. For economies to grow, they must become more complex.

  7. The Efficacy of Democracy and Freedom in Fostering Economic Growth

    The influence of democracy on a country's economic progress and income is an important and continuing debate among scholars. There has been extensive research to establish both a direct and indirect relationship between these two factors (Heo & Tan, 2001).The causal link between these factors is deep, intertwined, and complex (Salahodjaev, 2015).

  8. Research

    Research. The Growth Lab hosts an interdisciplinary team that iterates between theory and practice of economic development to improve our understanding of how economies grow. Our trademark methodologies, Economic Complexity and Growth Diagnostics, have revolutionized development thinking and inspired many places to reconsider their economic ...

  9. Research Effort and Economic Growth

    The increase in research effort by 1% increases TFP growth by more than 1%, and the increase in the number of researchers has been associated with declining TFP growth. Tables 11 and 12 are summaries of the parameter estimates. The overall results indicate that (1) the increase in research effort increases TFP growth.

  10. The Role of Research and Development in Economic Growth: A Review

    This paper reviews the role of Research and Development in the economic growth. The paper links back the story of economic growth to the studies of 17 th and 18 th century. The role of Research ...

  11. Study: Democracy fosters economic growth

    Study the "switchers". Acemoglu and Robinson have worked together for nearly two decades on research involving the interplay of institutions, political systems, and economic growth. The current paper is one product of that research program. To conduct the study, the researchers examined 184 countries in the period from 1960 to 2010.

  12. Economic Growth: Articles, Research, & Case Studies on Economic Growth

    Economic Growth. New research on economic growth from Harvard Business School faculty on issues including whether the US economy can recapture the powerful growth rates of the past, how technology adoption affects global economies, and why India's economy is expected to overtake China's. Page 1 of 19 Results.

  13. Role of Research in Economic Growth

    THE United States has probably the highest economic growth rate among the highly industrialized countries of the world. The United States is also distinguished by devoting the highest percentage of its national income to research and development. There is a definite correlation between these two facts. Research is a highly creative activity—it produces new products, creates new jobs and new ...

  14. New insights into the impact of financial inclusion on economic growth

    Financial inclusion is critical to inclusive growth, proffering policy solutions to eradicate the barriers that exclude individuals from financial markets. This study explores the effects of financial inclusion on economic growth in a global perspective with a large number of panels classified by income and regional levels from 2002-2020. The ...

  15. Financial Inclusion and Economic Growth: Evidence-Based Research

    Financial inclusion benefits the economy as the financial resources become available in a transparent manner for multiple uses and higher financial returns but this area calls for extensive research. In the Indian context, financial inclusion has been defined as 'the process of ensuring access to financial services, timely and adequate credit ...

  16. Policies to Promote Economic Growth in the United States

    Our view is that this debate about the implications of technological advances for economic growth suggests two broad directions for public policy. First, the United States should promote future productivity growth by facilitating increased innovation, including in AI, robotics, and digital sensors. Expanded government support for research and ...

  17. Research: How Entrepreneurship Can Revitalize Local Communities

    Summary. Much has been written about the potential for entrepreneurship to spur economic growth — and yet time and time again, we've seen business-driven revitalization programs fail to make a ...

  18. The Crucial Role of Workforce Development Programs in Fostering

    Thus, workforce development programs play a pivotal role in shaping the economic landscape of any country or region. These programs are designed to enhance the skills, knowledge, and capabilities of the workforce, ensuring they remain competitive, adaptable, and relevant in an ever-evolving job market. This two-part article explores the crucial ...

  19. Enhancing labor productivity as a key strategy for fostering green

    Renewable energy is a clean and sustainable source of energy that can help to reduce emissions and reliance on fossil fuels. Expected output: GDP (G2) Green GDP: Data are from the World Bank Green Growth Indicators Database. Green GDP is a measure of economic growth that takes into account environmental and social factors. Non-expected output

  20. How the Government Can Help Stimulate Economic Growth

    Abstract. This chapter, which is mainly based on Forrest et al. (to appear, The role government policy and supports play to stimulate economic growth), studies the following three issues: (1) why policy tools of the government might work in real life; (2) when they do work, what the underlying mechanism is through which implemented policies ...

  21. How Does Innovation Affect Economic Growth? Evidence from G20 Countries

    For instance, economic growth usually attracts trade openness (Burange et al., 2019), and trade openness leads economies to specialise in sectors that have a comparative advantage and can therefore foster the welfare-enhancing restructuring of countries' production and innovation structures (see OECD, 2012). Therefore, the relationship ...

  22. The role of innovations in fostering economic growth: an empirical

    The purpose of this paper is to foster realistic reflections on the importance of stimulating research and development activities within national enterprises employing over 250 employees, based on ...

  23. Ensuring that no one is left behind

    A critical channel from growth to prosperity relates to the capacity of growth to generate productive employment and decent work. This is critical in order to leave no one behind. The 2030 Agenda recognizes that economic growth is not sufficient to ensure that all human beings can enjoy prosperous and fulfilling lives.